2003
From social contract to private contracts: The privatisation of health, education and basic infrastructure - A review of the 2003 Social Watch country reports
Tim Kessler
Citizens' Network on Essential Services
Privatisation is being pushed by international governance institutions, the governments that control them, and the corporations that lobby both groups, even though the dangers that privatisation entails can seriously-and permanently-harm the livelihoods of the world?s poorest people. The position of ?privatise first and ask questions later? and the naïve confidence in the processes and outcomes of market reform have imposed hardship on precisely the groups those organisations are entrusted to protect. It is time to shift the burden of proof from those who question risky solutions to those who propose them.
The privatisation of basic public services has become a dominant
issue in policy discourse in industrialised as well as developing countries.
Over the last few years, policies affecting water, electricity, health and
education in some countries have generated as much political controversy and
social mobilization as taxation, land reform or even trade.
What makes basic services so special? Market-oriented service
provision policies have been subject to an unprecedented level of public
scrutiny. From the perspective of diverse civil society movements, the issue of
basic services cuts across a wide range of issue areas, such as: accountability
and transparency of international governance institutions, human rights, poverty
reduction, democratization, national sovereignty, gender equality, debt
reduction and cancellation, and environmental protection.
Policy-oriented NGOs that advocate for a particular cause are now
putting public services on their agenda. For example, a number of citizen
organisations with experience in monitoring the Bretton Woods institutions have
taken a sudden interest in the General Agreement on Trade in Services, a WTO
agreement that could ?lock in? privatisation (making it practically
irreversible) and undermine the ability of governments to regulate or even
finance public services.
There is also a special economic dimension to some basic
services. In the case of water and electricity, distribution tends to be a
natural monopoly. Physical reliance on a single water pipe network (and often a
single water source) or a common power grid leaves little room for competition.
The monopolistic dimension of basic infrastructure makes a highly competent,
well-funded and politically autonomous government regulator essential for
privatisation. Yet in the poorest countries where private provision is promised
to bring the greatest benefit, these institutional preconditions are almost
always missing. In the absence of effective regulation, private monopolies can
charge whatever they wish and can largely ignore customer preferences, thus
making a mockery of claims about the benefits of competition.
On one hand, the Bretton Woods institutions and their major
shareholder governments tout the benefits of privatising the public sector. A
discussion draft of the World Bank?s 2004 World Development Report, whose
theme is services for the poor, states that neither growth nor public spending
increases will improve services enough to reach the Millennium Development Goals
(MDGs). It then argues that achieving the MDGs requires a rejection of the
current government provision model of service delivery and the adoption of
reforms that largely bypass the state, including private concessions and
sub-contracting.
On the other hand, civil society organisations across the global
North and South are increasingly resisting the adoption of policies that put
basic services into private hands. Some privatisation measures have led to
spontaneous citizen mobilization that threatened the survival of national
governments. Given the relevance of basic service provision to reducing poverty
and its growing visibility, the authors of the 2003 Social Watch country reports
were asked to give special attention to the issue. Their findings are the
subject of this essay.
Basic services as a
human right
Citizen groups have mobilized resistance to privatisation of
essential services not only because they are necessary for survival and human
fulfilment, but also because of the undemocratic and indiscriminate manner in
which privatisation has been pursued. Although donors and creditors acknowledge
the importance of transparency and good governance, it is common for these
powerful institutions to require governments to commit to privatisation in
secret deal, hidden from public view. Without the knowledge, much less consent,
of citizens (and often even parliamentarians), public services are often
commercialised and leased for decades.
Privatisers are right to stress the importance of efficiency,
especially when it comes to traditional state-owned enterprises, such as
airlines, telecommunications or factories. However, equity and universal access
are more important than efficiency when it comes to essential services.
Efficiency gains through price hikes that end up limiting access may help the
balance sheet, but hurt the poor in the process.
Essential services are central to a ?social contract? between
government and citizens. While social contracts vary considerably across
countries, they generally promote equity and universality through redistributive
mechanisms that ensure a minimum level of access to goods or services that are
necessary for livelihood and dignity. Typical social contracts include
sufficient primary education to ensure literacy, basic health care, and access
to safe drinking water. More elaborate social contracts (in more developed
countries) may also include sanitation services and household electricity.
Essential services are generally viewed as public goods. Unlike
private goods, all people benefit from universal access to public goods,
regardless of how much they consume. For example, clean water and accessible
health care reduce the overall incidence of illness (e.g., epidemics).
Similarly, universal education increases economic productivity and forms the
foundation of meaningful citizenship, thus benefiting even those without
school-age children.
The social contract is based on two related premises: first, that
governments should be held accountable for delivery of basic services; and
second, that individuals or communities can and should exercise their
citizenship rights to ensure those services (at least in democracies).
Life-sustaining services such as drinking water are increasingly the subject of
national campaigns to guarantee human rights with special legislation or
constitutional amendments.
The human rights perspective on basic services has been
articulated at a global level. In November 2002, the United Nations Committee on
Economic, Cultural and Social Rights declared access to water to be a
fundamental right. It also stated that water is a social and cultural good, and
not only an economic commodity. The Committee emphasized that the 145 nations
that have ratified the International Covenant on Economic, Cultural and Social
Rights are now bound by the agreement to promote access to safe water
?equitably and without discrimination?. Although the UN declaration did not
specifically refer to the policy of privatisation-perhaps out of the desire to
avoid open conflict with powerful member governments that support it-it implied
that state provision was the best option for allocation
?a limited natural resource and a public commodity fundamental to
life and health?.
Earlier in the year, the United Nations Commission on Human Rights (UNCHR) laid
the analytical and moral foundations for the November declaration, when it
released a report
that urged WTO member nations to consider the human rights implications of
liberalising trade in services, especially health, education and water. The
UNCHR report establishes the case that trade is subject to human rights law: ? International
trade law and human rights law have grown up more or less in isolation from each
other. Yet as trade rules increasingly broaden their scope into areas that
affect the enjoyment of human rights, commentators are recognizing the links
between the two, seeking to understand how human rights and trade interact, in
an attempt to provide greater coherence to international law and policy-making
and a more balanced international and social order... The legal basis for
adopting human rights approaches to trade liberalisation is clear... A human
rights approach sets as entitlements the basic needs necessary to lead a life in
dignity and ensures their protection in the processes of economic
liberalisation.?
The Report then focuses specifically on the relationship between
services and human rights, and the potential effects of liberalisation: ?Importantly,
services act as an essential input into the production of goods and even other
services and as a result can facilitate growth and development... Not only can
services liberalisation affect economic growth and trade, it can also have an
impact on the provision of essential entitlements accepted as human rights such
as health care, education and water... However, the liberalisation of trade in
services, without adequate governmental regulation and proper assessment of its
effects, can also have undesirable effects. Different service sectors require
different policies and time frames for liberalisation and some areas are better
left under governmental authority.?
The human rights perspective is far from abstract or theoretical.
It is based on experiences in the real world. The case for balancing the values
of economic efficiency and fiscal prudence with a human rights framework is
supported not only by common sense, but also by evidence. There have been many
disappointments with privatisation policies, and more than a few outright
disasters. As private provision of services has accelerated over the last five
to ten years, more episodes of soaring prices, poor quality and corruption are
added to the public record.
Current policy trends suggest that the social contract-or even
the potential for a future social contract-is being replaced by private
contracts between governments and providers. Citizens with rights to demand
accountability are being transformed into mere consumers who are, at best,
indirect parties to contracts.
The implications for access and affordability put private
provision at the heart of the debate over human rights. When poor households
cannot afford access to drinking water, primary education or basic medical
attention, the stakes of privatisation policies loom as large as life itself.
The impacts can directly result in death, disease, misery, or a stunted life,
whereas the impacts of other key policies, such as trade liberalisation or tax
increases, while serious, are more indirect.
Surely, public sector provision also has a lamentable record in
many countries. However, public services often become viable before they are
sold or leased, proving that improvement is possible. In addition, recent
experiences with transparency and accountability measures have empowered
citizens to demand more responsive services. The immediate and direct connection
of basic services to human rights, survival and livelihoods ensures that private
sector participation will remain highly a visible and contentious economic issue
around the world.
Country experiences
While the Social Watch country reports do not constitute a
scientific study of private provision of basic services, they do provide a
considerable amount of disturbing evidence about the impacts and processes of
privatisation. In country after country we learn about price hikes and social
exclusion, poor service quality, and the implementation of policies without even
minimal levels of transparency. Privatisation proponents are likely to argue
that the stories told in these reports are merely anecdotal. Yet as a body of
evidence, the Social Watch reports reveal important patterns that simply cannot
be dismissed, and make a compelling case for rethinking privatisation policies
and budget austerity.
Process of privatisation
One of the most troubling aspects of the privatisation process
identified by Social Watch reports from developing countries is external
interference. Private provision policies are often imposed by multilateral
lending institutions. During the 1990s, the World Bank, IMF and IDB conditioned
major loan packages to Ecuador upon the privatisation of the public water
utility. The financial institutions oversaw secret contract negotiations that
guaranteed high returns and led to one of the most publicized water price hike
disasters, and ultimately to a political crisis that eventually sent the private
firm packing.
In Ghana, the World Bank?s Country Assistance Strategy (CAS)
?classifies ?private sector involvement? in the provision, operation and
management of public and social infrastructure as a key institutional reform?,
which, when implemented, will increase levels of Bank financing. Similarly, in
its 1998 CAS for Mexico, the World Bank pushed hard for the privatisation of
electricity, despite massive popular resistance and a deplorable record of
corruption and price hikes following previous sell-offs. (As of this writing,
political opposition has stalled that privatisation drive.)
The Morocco report states that World Bank assistance in extending
the water network to poor neighbourhoods was conditioned ?to the adoption of
a policy adjusted to actual market prices, without considering either the
special urban structure of these neighbourhoods or the solvency of their
residents.? The Social Watch report for Bolivia, home to one of the world?s
most notorious privatisation failures, explains how water policy was dictated
from beyond national borders: ?Since the beginning of
the 1990s, the World Bank had been demanding privatisation of the municipal
water company, SEMAPA, as the only solution to the water problem in Cochabamba.
In 1996, the WB conditioned a USD 14 million loan to SEMAPA to its
privatisation. And in 1997, the IMF, WB and IDB conditioned debt cancellation of
another USD 600 million to the privatisation of SEMAPA. ?the WB demanded a
rigorous application of full cost recovery; and the company managed to establish
a guaranteed high rate of returns during the negotiations. All these
costs-reached by consensus during an absolutely secret process between the
company, the government and local elites-were to be reflected in the water rates
prior to any improvement in the water system.?
Impacts of private provision
Given its primary commitment, for Social Watch the ultimate
consideration for analysis of privatisation, or any other economic policy, is
the impact on the poor. It is in this area that the record of private provision
causes the greatest cause for concern. By far the most pervasive impact of
service privatisation identified in the Social Watch reports is increased
prices, which inevitably lead to social exclusion. As the South Africa report
wryly put it: ?The real citizens are those with cash.?
In the case of infrastructure services, privatisation has often
combined a profit-maximizing incentive with monopoly power. Examples abound.
During the late 1990s, the privatisation of electricity in Brazil led to a 65%
increase for residential consumers, far higher than the rate of inflation. In
Peru, privatised electricity companies, under no restrictions on setting
tariffs, raised real prices by a factor of 14 between 1992 and 2002.
The many
faces of privatisation
The
narratives on basic services in the Social Watch reports suggest that
?privatisation? is experienced through different policies across countries
and service sectors. The most direct form of privatisation is divestiture:
the permanent sale of public assets to the private sector. This usually
involves a formal public auction, with the winner offering the highest
bid. Another form of privatisation is a long-term concession, in which the
state retains formal ownership but pays a firm (or NGO) to manage its
assets, make investments, and deliver specific services. (Certain
variations on concessions, such as the lease or affermage, do not require
the private operator to finance investments.) A common variation on the
lease, especially in energy and water services, is the
?Build-Operate-Transfer? arrangement, in which a firm constructs and then
manages a utility over a long period of time, before turning the assets
over the government.
The word
?privatisation? is gradually disappearing from documents produced by
development banks. The preferred term for virtually any form of private
sector control over services is now ?public-private partnership? (PPP).
While the term ?partnership? evokes ideas of cooperation and mutual
interest, PPPs are essentially adversarial relationships in which the
state?s responsibility is shifted from providing services directly to
making sure that someone else does. In health and education, a common type
of PPP is ?contracting out,? in which the government can sub-contract
services with firms or NGOs ranging from school and hospital maintenance,
to education and medical care. While there are significant differences
between ?final sale? privatisation and lease or management forms of PPPs,
all require contracts, government monitoring, regulation and enforcement.
And most require incentives or public resources in order to serve poor
people.
Many
Social Watch reports identified commercial pricing as a prelude to
privatisation. While the introduction and increase in user fees does not
remove the government from direct provision of basic services, many
authors conceive of the market logic that requires even the poorest
citizens to dedicate more of their private income for these essentials as
preparation for private provision. Finally, many identify what one report
describes as privatisation ?by default?. The erosion of public resources
needed to maintain quality public services-often accompanied by
deregulation allowing private sector participation and investment-has
resulted in decreasing quality of public services and a corresponding
growth of private provision of services, for those who can pay.
|
In Bulgaria, the privatised water monopoly raised prices twice
within three years despite a contract stipulating stable prices during that
period. In Ghana, where water rates increased sharply in the mid 1980s and early
1990s, the Social Watch report cites recent research that concludes: ?The
commercialisation of water [has] led the poor to see water supply as a
key factor in their poverty-striken situation.?
Private provision of key social services has also resulted in
increased costs for public providers, and ultimately to taxpayers. In Malaysia
in the mid 1990s, privatisation of essential medical services such as drugs and
hospital supplies, led directly to increased costs for government provision of
health care without improvements in services. The 1996 privatisation of support
services such as maintenance, equipment and cleaning increased operational costs
four to five times.
In other cases, while private provision may not yet have been
implemented, the price of public services has gone up. In particular,
cost-recovering ?user fees? on public services have been imposed by governments
that lack the budget (or perhaps the political commitment) to deliver universal
basic services, especially in health and education. In Colombia, education
reforms in the 1990s have forced parents to pay for a wide range of
school-related services, including building maintenance, academic materials,
phone, water and electricity-even the salaries of janitors and secretaries!
While increased user fees are a great burden to those who can pay
them, they can be catastrophic for those who cannot. The South Africa report
cited a study, conducted by a prestigious research institute that revealed that
almost 10 million people had their water service disconnected between 1994 and
2002, primarily as the result of non-payment. (Private provision was launched in
1997) There were reports that disconnections in poor rural communities and urban
squatter settlements have forced some to turn to contaminated water sources,
causing cholera outbreaks and resulting in hundreds of deaths.
Another worrisome trend that emerges from the Social Watch
reports is gradual privatisation that has resulted not from a deliberate policy
choice, but rather from neglect. To borrow a telling phrase from the Uruguay
report, privatisation is occurring ?by default,? as government fails to either
fund adequately or reform essential public services. In country after country,
public funding has continually decreased over time, leaving government-run
services vastly inferior to private ones. At the same time, deregulation and
even special incentives have enabled private providers to enter and expand in
the market for basic services. When commercially-priced private alternatives
co-exist with under-funded public services, the result is a ?two tier? system in
which those with sufficient income enjoy improved services, while the poor have
access to only those of the low quality.
In Chile, a country with strong institutions and impressive
economic growth, education reform has helped channel public subsidies to private
schools that are free to select among the most prepared and well-off students.
As municipalities with fewer resources are forced to take on more low-income
students, quality has suffered, inducing more parents to reject free public
education.
In Costa Rica, where quality public education has been a major
factor in social equity and high living standards, a private school boom now
draws better off students away from public schools with declining resources. As
the authors of the country report lament, ?Thus, education has changed from
being a mechanism for social mobility to becoming an instrument of status and
exclusion.? The Malaysia report repeats an alarmingly common theme across
countries: ?two systems have emerged: higher quality private education for
those who can afford it and poorer quality public education for those with low
incomes.? The Nepal and Uganda reports present virtually identical outcomes
of income-based social exclusion in health and education.
In
addition to addressing the impact on the poor and general performance problems,
many Social Watch reports also focused on the effects of privatisation on
specific vulnerable groups. A considerable number of reports discussed the
impact of service privatisation on women. The Honduras report speaks for many:
?The disappearance of State responsibility for maintaining public services
has led to women having to double or treble their workday to take on a greater
workload at home, with more hours of voluntary work in the communities and in
activities generating income, to the detriment of their health, quality of life
and leisure.?
In Chile, where health insurance is subject to commercial
pricing, insurance premiums for women of child-bearing age are three to four
times higher that those for men in the same age bracket. Under the logic of
market pricing, ?women?s reproductive life is penalised?. Similarly in
Colombia, commercialised health insurance has not only reduced significantly the
overall percentage of people with coverage, but also discriminated against
women, a slight majority that represents only 39% of those with insurance.
Some
reports also explored the relationship between privatisation and traditional
community approaches to service provision. The Thailand report was particularly
emphatic about the role of culture and ?local voices of wisdom? in the
management of water resources. In discussing planned reform river basin
management, the report stated: ?The top-down participation [proposed by] the
state will involve an organisation of water user groups and a river basin
sub-committee that will oversee the local water resource management and lay down
strict rules for all water users, whose management methods are different owing
to their communal cultures. Moreover, each river basin is ecologically different
and features different irrigation systems that require various management and
maintenance techniques.?
The report went on to argue that water ?knowledge? required not
only technical know-how, but also an appreciation of sustainability in a given
socio-cultural context. From this perspective, natural changes-even those that
cause uncertainty in production-are seen as ?normal phenomena? that people
should not seek to control. Moreover, the traditional community-based approach
is not driven by the premise that optimal efficiency maximizes output, but
rather that moderation ensures sustainability.
Performance and
quality
Privatisation proponents routinely assert that private firms
deliver services more efficiently, with higher quality, and pay more attention
to customer needs. Sometimes they do. And sometimes they don?t. Before being
resold in 2002, Bulgaria?s private water company routinely overcharged
customers, randomly cut off services, and failed to respond to consumer
complaints. Between 2000 and 2001, El Salvador?s privatised electric companies
could do no better than 44,000 power outages and a half million customer
complaints. Among customers of the country?s main electricity distributor, one
in three had a complaint.
For Malaysia?s electricity users, frequent outages are still a
major problem years after privatisation. Following the privatisation of the
urban water systems of Rabat and Tetuan in Morocco, prices increased while
service was characterized by unclear, irregular and often extremely inaccurate
billing. In the Nicaragua report, the list of complaints resulting from
electricity privatisation is breathtaking: ?The
monopoly has violated approved regulations, schedules of rates, and scope,
conditions and quality of service. The ?corporate encouragement? they received
allowed them to operate with impunity towards users and pay no attention to
claims for collection of unfairly charged rates (errors in invoicing,
non-recorded energy, overdue payments, etc.), altered readings of the metres,
services paid for but not delivered for public street lighting, voltage
failures, damage to small domestic appliances, loss of products by companies,
and so on.?
A future for public services?
The stories presented in the Social Watch reports, as well as
extensive evidence gathered from all over the world, reveal the privatisation of
basic services to be a risky policy choice that can harm vulnerable groups and
rule out the establishment of a social contract that promotes equity. In
infrastructure services, transferring a natural monopoly to a private firm often
leads to higher prices. This is particularly likely in the absence of a capable
and autonomous regulator, which is typically the case in developing countries
with weak institutions. In the social services, user fees and the deterioration
of public health care and education quality hit the poor hardest. Budget cuts
and incentives for private providers to attract better off consumers impose poor
quality and limited access upon those without cash in hand.
To assert that private sector participation in services always
results in poor performance or social exclusion is certainly an exaggeration. To
argue that this reform approach often fails to deliver promised benefits and has
hurt the poor is not. Nevertheless, in spite of troubling outcomes in the
services that matter most to people?s lives, policies that promote private
provision are gaining momentum rather than causing circumspection.
Where does this momentum come from? First, it comes from budget
crises. In all too many cases, privatisation, whether through increased user
fees or sale of assets, is primarily a macroeconomic measure to cut public
deficits or reduce debt levels. As Lebanon report argues: ?The main reason
for privatisation in Lebanon is fiscal. With 85% of government spending going to
fixed expenditures (wages and debt servicing), there is little room for further
austerity. Government officials argue that the proceeds from massive
privatisation were Lebanon?s only way out of the debt trap.?
For many governments under pressure from the IMF to balance their
budgets, privatisation simply means revenue, not poverty reduction. After all,
according to the rationale behind fiscal discipline, deficits and debt can only
go so high, inflation must be controlled, and government can?t pay for
everyone?s needs. That is true enough. But it begs the question: What can and
should government provide for its citizens, and through what means? It
doesn?t seem terribly daring to assert that basic services should be very high
on any government's list of priorities.
Yet by pushing for privatisation and commercialisation of these
services, powerful countries and global institutions actually make it much
easier for governments to neglect their most basic obligations and avoid tough
political choices needed to meet them. If citizens must dig deep into their
pockets to pay for water and health care, government can spend public resources
elsewhere, even if the poor do not benefit. Moreover, when services are
available on a ?cash only? basis, political leaders need not pursue progressive
taxation or cross-subsidy arrangements that might irritate influential groups.
Another reason for the mainstreaming of service privatisation is
that in many cases, public services perform very badly or exclude the poor. Many
Social Watch reports identify highly inadequate and unreliable government
services that often exclude the poor. The need to improve such services is a
more defensible position than balancing budgets. The argument is compelling: ?If
services are already low quality or widely unavailable, how could any reform
make things worse??
Two responses to the privatisers? moralistic argument are in
order. First, the problem of bad services simply cannot be isolated from the
fiscal constraints described above. Privatisation proponents instinctively blame
unsatisfactory public services on incompetence or corruption. While these are
certainly factors at times, insufficient resources have seriously eroded public
sector capacity over twenty years of budget austerity. Through what has been
dubbed the ?defund and defame? strategy, as government services become worse or
more expensive (or both), citizens become less resistant to private sector
alternatives. Second, as so many Social Watch reports demonstrate, privatising a
failing public service is no guarantee for serving the poor. While a private
firm may increase efficiency, it may do so in part by raising prices beyond the
reach of the poor.
(One clever suggestion to solve this problem is to provide a
subsidy for poor consumers or directly to a company that serves low-income
people who cannot pay market prices. However, longstanding difficulties in
targeting subsidies make this approach unworkable in countries with weak
institutions for identifying and registering the poor. More to the point, it
raises the question: why provide scarce public resources for a profit-maximizing
enterprise instead of at least attempting to reform the existing public service
first?)
Finally, privatisation is being pushed by international
governance institutions, the governments that control them, and the corporations
that lobby both groups. As examples from the reports illustrate, the World Bank
has used loan conditionalities to promote privatisation of services,
commercialisation of prices and liberalisation of foreign investment in basic
service sectors. In 2001, the International Finance Corporation, the Bank?s
private sector arm, targeted infrastructure and social services as ?frontier
sectors? for privatisation.
The Bank?s 2002 Private Sector Development (PSD) strategy, which
was strongly promoted by the Bush Administration, envisions the segregation of
profit-making from loss-making services. Dividing up customers in this way
facilitates ?cherry-picking? or ?cream-skimming? by businesses that buy up the
profitable services (i.e., those catering to those with sufficient cash income,
primarily urban and middle class consumers) and leave the unprofitable services
(i.e., those used by the poor) to the government or non-governmental
organisations. The arrangement could permanently rule out the possibility of
public cross-subsidies, in which wealthier consumers help cover costs for
low-income consumers. It could institutionalise the two-tier system described in
so many Social Watch reports, leaving low quality services for the poor.
The world?s premier development organisation recently released a
working draft of its 2004 World Development Report (WDR), entitled Making
Services Work for the Poor. Using highly selective evidence and paying scant
attention to downside risks, the document promotes replacing national public
services with private firms, NGOs or local government and communities. It
largely dismisses the option of increasing public funding, and completely
ignores the role of adjustment lending in eroding public service budgets. Given
that many properly funded public services work well even in very poor countries,
and given a better understanding of how transparency and citizen participation
can increase the accountability of public institutions, the WDR?s silence on
reform of existing government services seems to be based more on ideology than
analysis.
The mixed record of private provision of basic services does not
justify a categorical rejection of privatisation policies. In the same vein,
poor performance among some government-run services hardly justifies the global
rollback of the state now being carried out by the leading development
institutions. Determining whether reform of services should be undertaken
through private provision or under state control should be done through an
analysis of social needs and institutional conditions on a case-by-case basis.
However, because the risks of privatisation can seriously-and
permanently-harm the livelihoods of the world?s poorest people, a cautious
approach to reform is appropriate. Today the international lending institutions
have taken the position of ?privatise first and ask questions later?. In too
many cases, such naïve confidence in the processes and outcomes of market reform
has imposed hardship on precisely the groups those organisations are entrusted
to protect. It is time to shift the burden of proof from those who question
risky solutions to those who propose them.
Notes
For a detailed glossary of PPP types, see ?Public-Private Partnerships:
Terms Related to Building and Facility Partnerships?, United States
Government Accounting Office, April 1999, available at: http://www.gao.gov/special.pubs/Gg99071.pdf
|