2002
The Monterrey Consensus: consolidate globalisation at the expense of women
Marina Fe B. Durano
Development Alternatives with Women for a New Era (DAWN)
The unwritten consensus of the so-called Monterrey Consensus continues to use the institutionally embedded social reproductive roles of women to support global economic production.
For
over 50 years, development has focused on economic growth. The International
Conference on Financing for Development (FfD) offers no a radical shift away
from this perspective.[1] The Monterrey Consensus consolidates the forces of
globalisation. It seeks to expand global capital by promoting foreign direct
investment, integrate the poor into the global market through market access for
exports, and legitimate the supremacy of the World Bank-International Monetary
Fund-World Trade Organisation in economic governance. The unwritten consensus
continues to use the institutionally embedded social reproductive roles of women
to support global economic production.
It
should come as no surprise that FfD has not lent itself to a discussion of
gender perspectives in global macroeconomic policymaking. A gender analysis of
macroeconomics is itself a relatively new area of study, with some aspects
better studied than others, eg, gender
budget analysis and gender and trade. Thus, the inclusion of gender language in
the Monterrey Consensus is limited to the use of gender-sensitive descriptive
qualifiers, listing of special concerns with inclusion of women and gender
mainstreaming. There is a strong need to disseminate the elements of a gender
analysis of macroeconomics at the many levels of policymaking in order broaden
the discourse on the examination of globalisation.
A
corollary weakness of the Monterrey Consensus is the absence of human rights
language as a framework for proposed actions despite reference to upholding the
United Nations Charter. This absence is incongruent with the commitment to the
principles of justice and equity found in the document. Since the Monterrey
Consensus will form part of a body of soft law—“strictly formulated
obligations but contained in recommendatory non-binding instruments”—the
absence of human rights language inhibits the Monterrey Consensus from providing
a solid normative framework for the formation of law and binding legislation.[2]
Gender
and macroeconomics
Separation
of social policy and macroeconomic policy
Macroeconomic
policy and social policy are often discussed as separate concerns in public
policy. Macroeconomic policy is implemented in pursuit of economic stability and
growth. Social policy is implemented in pursuit of social objectives such as
universal education and disease prevention. Macroeconomic policy deals with hard
issues while social policy deals with soft issues. Most often, women’s issues
are identified with social policy and remain invisible in macroeconomic policy
formulation.
Bridging
this divide through proper integration of both policy spheres would be an
important first step. Unfortunately, the Monterrey Consensus fails to take this
bold step. Rather, it has chosen to promote social protection and social safety
nets, which are seen as appropriate responses to social risks. This approach has
been criticised by Esping-Andersen[3]
as inappropriate to today’s realities. In addition, the mainstream approaches
to social protection that substitute for social policy in the Asian economies in
the aftermath of the 1997 crisis are inadequate. These were formulated as an
afterthought to macroeconomic policy and are considered by Elson and Cagatay[4]
as an “adding on social policy approach”. A severe criticism of safety nets
as envisioned by multilateral and regional funding agencies is that safety nets
are designed only to deal with “shocks” as if these were coming from outside
the system of production rather than produced by it.
Social
policy is seldom formulated using the principles of social justice. Doing so
would create a set of instruments that could help eliminate exploitative
relations in both the productive and reproductive spheres of economic and social
activity that create and exacerbate poverty and inequality.
The
social content of macroeconomic policy
The
usual approach to a gender analysis of macroeconomic policy is to investigate
the social impact of a set of policies. Elson and Cagatay[5]
look deeper into the social content of macroeconomic policy by identifying the
power structures that drive the direction of macroeconomic policy. Three biases
that work against women are highlighted.
A
deflationary bias brought about by high interest rates makes it
difficult for businesses to remain viable. In times of economic crisis, women
are disproportionately negatively affected through job losses in the formal
sector, increased crowding in the informal sector, and greater household
responsibilities as women help their families cope with the crisis. Financial
bailouts are more common than social bailouts.
A
male breadwinner bias is created by the reliance on full employment
and economic growth to meet social goals, coupled with the assumption that
men—the main providers of labour in the formal sector—support a set of
dependents, usually women, children, and the elderly. Exemplified by European
welfare states, women are dependent on men for social benefits provided by the
state. Women, who largely comprise the informal sector and part-time workers, do
not have access these benefits.
A
commodification bias manifests itself when government spending
policy is defined in terms of minimising the budget deficit. Social services are
increasingly privatised making access even more difficult for the poor. The lack
of publicly-provided services is made up for by women who are expected to bear
the caring responsibilities in a household.
Since
women are rarely seen and heard in the hallowed halls where macroeconomic policy
is formulated, their issues and concerns are rarely reflected in the
decision-making processes. This imbalance at the national level is mirrored at
the global level when ministers of finance and governors of central banks gather
to determine the direction of global macroeconomic processes.
Gender
relations embedded in institutions
Gender
norms are embedded in institutions, defined as a set of structures that govern
economic and social behaviour. Existing gender relations enforce an arrangement
where the caring support found in households and social organisations makes
market activities possible. The implementation of macroeconomic policy in this
supportive setting without acknowledging its role and influence results in the
biases described above.
Existing
gender norms place an additional burden on women who want to participate in the
market but are hindered from doing so because of socially determined limitations
on physical mobility and ownership of assets. In some cases, norms are
formalised in marriage customs and legal structures. As DAWN articulated in its
intervention during the Third Preparatory Committee Meeting of the FfD, “[t]he
goal of creating a truly enabling financial environment in support of
development that will equally benefit women and men requires addressing
long-term institutional deficiencies and barriers to gender equality.”
From
national to global and back
The
discussion has so far engaged the realm of policymaking at the national level.
While many national weaknesses are replicated at the global level, the
replication is not straightforward. The already well-known tension between
capital mobility and labour mobility, and trends in the segmentation of capital
and the segmentation of labour make the nature of gender biases more complex.
Furthermore,
globalisation severely challenges policymaking at the national level because of
increased pressure towards economic integration and the use of a single economic
model for growth. National economic sovereignty, with the nation-state as the
ultimate decision-maker over the use of its resources and other resources
located within its territories, can no longer be practised in a conventional
manner because economic borders have eroded. Multiple bilateral, regional, and
multilateral agreements on money and finance, investment, and trade have made
economic borders less clear and less defined. The range of policy instruments
available to developing countries today is narrower than that available to
developed countries when they were in a similar stage of development. Policy
discretion is heavily curtailed.
The
success of the FfD should be judged by its ability to resolve the tensions
arising from challenges to national economic sovereignty. As FfD discussions
progressed and entered into the negotiations phase, however, the pragmatic view
prevailed. Government stakeholders wanted everybody to “stay on board” and
this meant that the FfD could not be seen as a venue for resolving differences
on globalisation.
The
supremacy of capital mobility
The
Monterrey Consensus has sealed the supremacy of capital mobility in this era of
globalisation. This is expressed mainly as an “anti-tax” position, since the
proposal for an International Tax Organisation and the hotly contested Currency
Transactions Tax were removed from discussion after the Fourth Preparatory
Committee Meeting in January 2002. This is a matter of concern especially
considering Rodrik’s[6]
1997 findings that capital income’s share of total taxes has decreased and
labour income’s share has increased. In general, any mention of regulatory
measures on any form of capital has met with strong opposition, chiefly from
source countries.
In
contrast, there is no reference to migration except for the “movement of
persons” under the theme of international trade, referring to terminology used
by the World Trade Organisation in its General Agreement on Trade in Services.
This reference does not contain any commitments and only raises concern over
this and other trade matters important to developing and least developed
countries. The lack of commitments on migration despite the recommendation of
the Zedillo Report contradicts the intent to “open up opportunities for
all,” especially to those whose only asset is their labour.
Segmented
capital: portfolio flows vs. foreign direct investment
Even
capital and capitalists are now segmented and possibly working against each
other. Several financial crises resulting from uncontrolled short-term capital
inflows have destroyed national economies and forced closure of foreign firms
located in those economies. Foreign direct investment is still relatively
footloose. Huge losses may be incurred in moving operations from one country to
another and profitability can be threatened at any time by the onslaught of
crisis.
Foreign
short-term financiers find partners among national elite who own and control
local financial assets. An atmosphere is created where arbitrage becomes
profitable and domestic financial institutions are encouraged to engage in
risk-taking. These are often the same institutions that hold a conservative
stance regarding lending to poor people and to women. Not only are financial
intermediaries reluctant to lend to women, but women may also be reluctant to
borrow (risk-averse) because they hesitate to place the dependents in their
household at risk.[7]
In
contrast, women are more visible in relation to foreign direct investment
because they constitute a pool of workers in export processing zones and in
subcontracted work. The benefits of increased employment opportunities provided
to women need to be weighed against the nature of employment relations in these
firms and the impact on women’s work and status in their households.
In
addition, foreign direct investors are able to use their preferential position
to extract concessions from host governments in the form of government
contracts, infrastructure, and tax breaks. These revenue losses should be
sharply contrasted with the limits placed on social service expenditures.
Segmented
labour: skilled labour vs.
unskilled labour
There
is a high level of suspicion and general lack of interest in many countries
associated with the opening of borders to foreign labour. In agreeing to discuss
the movement of persons, the FfD may be acknowledging that globalisation could
offer increased opportunities to people with specialised skills or
professionals. Developed countries may become more amenable to porous borders as
their demographic profile becomes older and their working age population thins.
The opportunities offered, however, are mainly limited to middle class
households who can afford to get an education and pay for the costs of
migration. Whether such migration leads to an intensification of the “brain
drain” from developing countries has yet to be determined.
The
pattern of employment is sex-segregated by occupation. Teaching and nursing
professionals are predominantly women while engineers and architects are
predominantly men.
Low-skilled
and unskilled labourers often take risks using illegal channels of migration.
Low-skilled and unskilled labourers that remain in their home countries form the
reserve pool of labour available to domestic and foreign capitalists alike. This
process has undermined international solidarity among workers by pitting the
desperation of workers in poor countries against the threat of unemployment of
workers in rich countries.
Economic
and social governance: wherefore art thou, UN?
The
potential of the FfD to address long-term systemic problems underlying
development remains unrealised. The Monterrey Consensus failed to establish a
leadership role for the United Nations in global economic and social governance.
The Monterrey Consensus secured and legitimised the positions of the World Bank,
International Monetary Fund and World Trade Organisation in their respective
roles in global macroeconomic governance. The United Nations could have served
as a balancing force for these institutions, but the complete buy-in of the
policy prescriptions from the multilateral financial institutions only served to
consolidate the current nature and direction of globalisation.
Successfully
“staying engaged” in this arena requires decisive and assertive
reformulations of the global economic order in three inter-related areas:
international economic policymaking, international political economy, and
international economic law.[8]
On
international economic policymaking
An
open economic system naturally means that economic developments in one country
find translation into its partner economies. The major industrialised economies
whose currencies serve as the major trading instruments can cause disruptions in
the economies of their trading partners. Yet their policies promote their own
national interests (or the interests of a privileged small group), without
consideration of the impact these policies may have on their trading partners.
The
ad hoc and informal groups and networks that initiate policy are not
legitimate, since they lack transparency and have limited membership and,
therefore, undemocratic proceedings. In some instances, such as the Basle
Committee made up of the G-10’s central bank officials, legitimacy is
questioned because the officials are technocrats whose mandate for
representation is unclear. These groups must clarify and justify their
jurisdiction over the agenda they cover. If it is found that such groups are
necessary, then formal institutions should be established with clear mechanisms
for accountability and responsibility.
On
international political economy
Decision-making
processes in the various intergovernmental fora require serious restructuring.
Where voting structures depend on equity subscriptions, the richer countries
will get more votes. Where voting structures depend on exclusive membership,
outsiders will never get a vote. Even when voting structures appear level—as
in the one-state-one-vote process—voting power and real power still diverge.
Despite developing countries having two-thirds majority in the UN General
Assembly, these countries are unable to use their number to press for their
demands.
Suspicions
over the governance of multilateral groupings persuade countries to form blocks
or create side-agreements, which, strictly speaking, undermine the multilateral
agreements. Given the asymmetry in the balance of power described above, a
regional response can prove positive for weaker countries, particularly when
large influential nations are kept out. It is very important, however, that
regional responses create alternatives rather than imitate the content and
structure of the multilateral forums.
At
the national level, further clarification on the relationship between the
executive and legislative branches of government in forging international
agreements with domestic legislative implications is needed. Representative
democracy seems to be undermined when legislators are rarely if ever involved in
the process of negotiating agreements. National executive branch representatives
to multinational institutions must be held answerable for decisions made while
they were involved in the multilateral institutions.
On
international economic law
Much
of the discussion on the themes of the FfD has legal implications. Since these
are international agreements, they fall under the legal discipline of
international economic law. Apparently, international economic law is weak in
the area of international development law, where, as with many UN resolutions,
most formulations are not binding.[9]
Although agreements on trade, money and finance can have a developmental aspect,
they do not directly address development.
The
‘international agreements’ subset of the body of law must contain the
elements of fairness and justice since justice is a core principle of law.
Moreover, the relationship between international economic agreements and the
legal instruments of human rights and the right to development should be clearly
established, including at the national level.
Enabling
environment revisited
In
laying down the principles required to create an enabling environment for
raising financial resources for development, it should be remembered that such
action leads to attainment of the means to development, not to the ends that
make up development. The FfD should consider a redefinition of ‘enabling
environment’ for future work that involves viewing people as the end rather
than the means to development.
Macroeconomic
policy, particularly its employment generation component, aims to provide jobs
to the poor so that they can earn wages to pay for their consumption. In this
framework, people are a means for income generation and the growth of income is
equated with development.
Viewing
people as an end changes our perspective on macroeconomics. Policy instruments
build an external environment that enables each person’s capabilities to
function to the fullest. When a person’s internal capabilities are coupled
with this favourable external environment, “combined capabilities” are
developed. It is these combined capabilities that development process aims to
achieve. The enabling environment assures the existence of the social basis for
these capabilities.[10]
This
view stands in sharp contrast to policy that creates an enabling environment for
investment and growth. The promotion of investment and economic growth can only
provide the resources; it cannot guarantee that the resources made available
actually help a person function “in a truly human way.”
Social
justice and gender justice are better served in this redefinition as global
economic governance focuses its attention on the individuals that it hopes to
serve. This is particularly crucial for women who have “often been treated as
the supporters of the ends of others, rather than as ends in their own right”.
Development for all will be realised only when each person is treated as an end.
Notes:
[1]
United Nations. “Monterrey Consensus,” agreed draft text, final unedited
version, 27 January 2002, New York City.
[2]
Asif H. Qureshi. International
Economic Law. London: Sweet and Maxwell, 1999.
[3]
Gosta Esping-Andersen. “Social indicators and welfare monitoring,”
Social Policy and Development Paper No. 2, Geneva: United Nations Research
Institute for Social Development, 2000.
[4]
Diane Elson and Nilufer Cagatay. “The social content of macroeconomic
policies,” World Development 28(7)2000:
1347-64.
[6]
Dani
Rodrik. “Has Globalization Gone Too Far?” Washington DC: Institute for International Economics,
1997.
[7]
Diane Elson. “International financial architecture: A view from the
kitchen,” paper at the Annual Conference of the International Studies
Association in Chicago, February 2001, mimeo; Maria S. Floro.
“Gender
dimensions of the financing for development agenda,” working paper
prepared for UNIFEM, 22 April 2001, New York: UNIFEM.
[8]
Marina Fe B. Durano. “New
Goals for Global Governance?”, DAWN
Informs, November 2001. Excerpts of a presentation in the same titled
conference hosted by the Danish UN Association in Copenhagen.
[10]
Martha C. Nussbaum. Women and Human
Development: The Capabilities Approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2000.
|