2002
Building ownership of antipoverty strategies
Rob Mills; Lollo Darin-Ericson
European Network on Debt and Development (EURODAD)
While the PRSP approach is the new ‘wrapper’ for IFI operations and processes in low-income countries, replacing the old tripartite Policy Framework Paper, the actual contents of reform programmes have yet to show much change. This article highlights some of the main obstacles to a successful country-owned poverty reduction strategy and gives proposals on how to enhance country ownership.
In
September 1999, the Annual Meetings of the World Bank and International Monetary
Fund (IMF) announced a new poverty focus in the work of all the international
financial institutions (IFIs) in low-income countries. The most immediate and
concrete outcome of the new approach was the announcement of the new ‘Poverty
Reduction Strategy Papers’ (PRSPs). EURODAD has been closely following the
evolution of the PRSP process since its inception.
While
the PRSP approach is the new ‘wrapper’ for IFI operations and processes in
low-income countries, replacing the old tripartite Policy Framework Paper, the
actual contents of reform programmes have yet to show much change. This article
is based on a recent EURODAD policy paper “Many Dollars, Any Change?” in
which we highlight some of the main obstacles to a successful country-owned
poverty reduction strategy and give proposals on how to enhance country
ownership.[1]
Ownership
is vital
Recent debates in development
have stressed that ‘country ownership’ of strategies and programmes is key
to ensuring successful outcomes.[2]
Because ownership is an inherently ‘political’ concept, however, external
stakeholders face particular challenges when a country’s government is not
committed to poverty reduction.
What does ‘ownership’
actually mean: a useful concept?
As one commentator notes,
ownership is a concept “slippery and
unsatisfactory in many respects”.[3]
It is perhaps best seen as a ‘label’ for a broad concept whereby countries
take the initiative in (as well as being responsible and accountable for) their
efforts to reduce poverty through policy changes and reforms. Where ownership
has taken hold, one might expect to see countries being responsible for
formulating poverty reduction plans themselves, and for proactively
commissioning and organising technical and donor input into them, rather than
playing a passive role with external donors and creditors in the driving seat.
Ownership is a concept that
can be applied at many levels. The move to take responsibility for formulating
and implementing poverty strategies changes the relationship between national
governments and a range of external stakeholders (IFIs, bilateral donors, UN and
aid agencies, etc.) and might be
called ‘external’ ownership. Equally, ownership might be used to describe
how governments’ plans for poverty reduction have been drawn up within a
country. This ‘internal’ ownership would reflect the degree to which
internal stakeholders (parliaments, line ministries, private sector groups,
local civil society organisations, unions, faith-based groups, etc.) have been involved in the processes that result in a
particular set of policies being adopted by the government. Internal ownership
is thus closely bound up with participatory processes.[4]
Ownership implies a move away
from abstract, technical discussion of policy details to situating debates in
the political context of a country’s decision-making process. As one report
puts it, “politics matters” in development: “Poverty
reduction is, for better or worse, embedded in living political systems. This
implies that the PRSP ‘experiment’ will work through the political systems
and policy processes of the countries concerned, or it will not work at all.”
[5]
A
recent World Bank research report, Aid and
Reform in Africa, points out how, “Economic
policy is primarily driven by domestic politics, not by outside agents. The key
to successful reform is a political movement for change, and donors cannot do
very much to generate this. …The
ongoing use of conditionality disguises the true ownership of the reform
program, takes up valuable government time, and limits the participation in the
debate and decision-making about economic policy.”[6]
The point then is that
ownership of poverty strategies by country authorities is vital for ensuring
that those poverty strategies are successfully and sustainably implemented.
Outsiders’ money cannot ‘buy’ reforms that are not supported by the
authorities in the country.
This has profound implications
for the poverty reduction strategy (PRS) process on which many countries are
currently embarked, with the enthusiastic support of donors and creditors. If
getting pro-poor reforms implemented on a sustainable basis is key to poverty
reduction, then successfully fostering ownership will be vital to the success of
the PRS concept. It takes two to tango…
The
fostering of ownership in development co-operation is not a panacea for
alleviating poverty, however. More country ownership does not necessarily mean
that country authorities will miraculously propose and implement perfect
pro-poor strategies. As we noted in our previous PRS update,[7] many governments respond to powerful social forces and
economic actors whose priorities are not poverty reduction. The political
control in many societies lies with people who use the state for their narrow
interests. Therefore some groups will do everything to ensure that the status quo is maintained.[8]
Even proposed reforms that are
demonstrably "pro-poor" will not be implemented if they threaten
powerful vested interests. In Kenya, for example, the PRS process was viewed as
being ‘owned’ by a broad range of stakeholders. But progress in certain key
poverty aspects - good governance in particular - was recently stopped when an
older pattern of top-down presidential rule reasserted itself. One commentator
notes, “none of this necessarily means
that the Kenyan PRSP will have no benefits; but it does serve as a reminder that
the benefits will be constrained – but also enabled – by Kenya’s
particular realities.”[9]
The move to greater ownership implies a shifting of responsibility from
outsiders to governments. In a situation where the government shows little
willingness to bear that responsibility and little commitment to fighting
poverty, there is very little that outsiders can do.
External
and internal obstacles to greater country ownership
At theoretical and rhetorical
levels, the international development community has picked up quickly on these
themes. ‘Participation’ and ‘ownership’ are the new buzzwords,
compulsory in all documents, if hazily defined. Despite these changes in IFI
rhetoric, however, true ownership in development co-operation has yet to be
established. There is still a critical ‘credibility gap’, which is leading
civil society groups in many Southern countries to question the value of their
participation in PRS processes, and which thus threatens to undermine support
for the new approach. The following section identifies a series of external and
internal obstacles that prevent better ownership of countries’ poverty
reduction strategies.
‘External’
obstacles to increased ownership
One
set of obstacles to increased ownership is ‘external’: that is, relating to
external development partners:
·
Dominance
of the IFIs in agenda-setting and choices of reforms.
When a PRSP is completed the staffs of the World Bank (WB) and IMF write a
‘Joint Staff Assessment’ (JSA) of the PRSP, setting out their view of the
paper. The board then discusses the document and decides whether or not to
‘endorse’ it: that is, whether or not the JSA provides a sound basis for
future WB and IMF lending and debt relief. Gaining this IFI seal of approval is
vital to accessing not only IFI financing and debt relief, but also broader
donor support. As a result, PRSPs are necessarily written with the aim of having
them endorsed by the IFIs.[10]
There are several examples where the IFIs really shaped the whole process from
the beginning, as in Ghana where "Necessarily
put together in haste … there was heavy World Bank involvement in its
preparation and programmes included in it were drawn from the Bank's Country
Assistance Strategy document."[11]
·
A
tendency to ‘back-door’ policy specification. Another
concern has been the additional specification of policies and reforms in
documents other than the PRSP. This was an issue in the first couple of World
Bank PRSCs (Poverty Reduction Support Credit), where there was a tendency to
make up for the lack of specification in the PRSP by adding additional details
in the documentation for the PRSC, namely the Letter of Development Policy.
·
The
umbilical linkage between PRSPs and the HIPC Initiative.
Civil society groups have reported time and again that governments are rushing
PRS processes in order to achieve HIPC Initiative Decision or Completion Points.
Donors too have complained that the rush has damaged the quality of PRSPs. Even
IFI officials have admitted to us that the proposed solution to this tension,
the PRSP Initiative, has largely failed to mitigate the tension between
‘speed’ and ‘quality’. As such, the HIPC Initiative-PRSP linkage has
been a major structural obstacle to achieving high-quality country-owned
strategies.
·
Lack of
connection to broader international and national development processes.
A further structural obstacle to fostering country ownership is the relative
‘isolation’ of the preparation of PRSPs from broader development and
political processes. This happens both at the international level (eg,
the National Strategies for Sustainable Development adopted in the context of
the Rio+10 process, or the European Union’s Cotonou process), and at the
national level (eg, the disconnect
between Honduras’ PRSP and its ‘Master Plan for Reconstruction and
Transformation’ after Hurricane Mitch, or between Chad’s PRS process and its
mechanism for managing oil revenues).
·
Slow
movement of donors to budget support. The PRS
approach requires significant changes in donor behaviour. If PRS processes are
to result in a transfer of ownership, this implicitly implies a shift from
project-based aid towards budgetary support, on the basis that budget support
gives governments greater leeway to direct resources to the sectors prioritised
in their strategies. As one commentator puts it, "…the PRSP movement has also been associated with a fairly aggressive
assertion of the desirability of donors moving away from project-based aid in
favour of general programme or budget support."[12]
Through a combination of these
structural obstacles, the original aim of the PRSP to be the focus of all a
country’s efforts to combat poverty has not come to fruition. There is
evidence that the PRS approach has succeeded in removing poverty reduction
efforts from the ‘social sector ghetto’ and in tying expenditure decisions
more closely to poverty priorities. The impression has nonetheless developed
that PRSPs are somehow ‘separate’ and distinct from other aspects of a
country’s internal planning, and a product designed for the consumption of the
IFIs. Unfortunately, many groups in the South already perceive the PRSP as a
‘Washington thing’.
‘Internal’
obstacles to increased ownership
Structural impediments to
increasing ownership in countries’ development strategies are not just found
at the ‘external’ level. One must also look at domestic – and especially
governmental – impediments to preparing national poverty strategies.
·
Lack of
capacity. A lack of economic policymaking capacity
in poor countries, particularly in negotiations with IFIs and donors, often
leads to decisions that are not tailored to solving country-specific poverty
problems. A civil society report on the PRSP in Tanzania questions "...whether
macroeconomic policies are carefully and critically analysed, reviewed and
assessed as of their impact at the micro level, and on different stakeholders.
As a result the government is not in a position to take a proactive stand vis-à-vis
International Financial Institutions."[13]
The same arguments also apply to civil society groups: as a Ugandan civil
society organisation (CSO) puts it, “Many
CSOs lack the adequate capacity to engage in quality dialogues with stakeholders
such as the donors and even the government itself. A lot has to be done to
enhance the capacity of CSOs in the decision-making process.”[14]
·
Document
access. Making documentation available in a timely
fashion and in local languages remains an obstacle to wider participation. For
example, the recent Cambodian full PRSP was only made available in the local
language, Khmer, in the final version and not in earlier drafts. The fact that
the document had been prepared for the consumption of external donors in the
first instance meant that the opportunity for widespread input was lost.
·
Marginalisation
of CSOs. A continuing concern has been that
governments marginalise civil society in the preparation process, particularly
by leaving it out of the macro/structural reform debate in many cases, and by
failing to make substantive use of civil society proposals. In Tanzania, for
example, the government failed to catalyse substantive CSO involvement in the
recent Consultative Group process. It informed participants at very short notice
and conducted two parallel processes with informal and formal meetings.[15]
One NGO representative summed up the problem at a recent conference: “the
poor are not participating, they are being participated.”
.
·
Marginalisation
of parliaments. “PRSPs
have tended not to involve parliaments, as institutions, in a major way…it
would be unwise to allow parliaments to be as uninvolved as they have been until
now”.[16] Whilst it is not likely that all parliaments are
capable of playing a ‘watch-dog’ role, the lack of involvement of
parliamentarians in countries’ poverty strategies is a worrying development.
This has been a recurring theme in Southern CSOs’ analyses: in Malawi, for
example, the NGO network comments that “only
five MPs are involved in the PRSP process…key sectors are operating without
any parliamentary representation”.[17]
·
Institutions
often inaccessible to the poor. There has been
increasing recognition in recent years that well-functioning institutions
(courts, parliaments, the machinery of government, regulatory bodies and so
forth) are a vital aspect of a successful poverty strategy. The latest World
Bank World Development Report takes as
its central theme the need to strengthen the institutions that support markets
and private sector activity, including property rights, competition regulation
and anti-corruption laws.[18]
Furthermore, poor people have to be able to use the institutions – and if they
are not accessible to them, then they are as good as useless.
·
A focus
on budgets misses key inter-sectoral issues. Many
governments have convened working groups to draw up drafts for different parts
of the country strategy, generally with the involvement of key stakeholders.
They have tended to be organised, however, by ‘spending sectors’ that can be
linked directly to the budget (eg,
‘health’, ‘environment’, ‘infrastructure’, etc.).
Whilst linking the strategy directly to the budget is vital for ensuring that
spending is on the prioritised areas and is pro-poor, it appears in many cases
that this has been done at the expense of addressing cross-sectoral issues: “one
problem … is the failure of most groups to address cross-cutting themes.”[19]
·
Complementary
‘administrative’ changes needed. One
interesting donor comment on PRSPs is that “PRSPs
are unlikely to achieve very much on their own, but depend for their impact on
the existence of parallel changes in government financial and staff management
arrangements.”[20]
A consensus has emerged that the countries where the PRS process is proceeding
most successfully are where it is connected to ongoing public-sector reforms,
particularly of public-finance management.
Proposals to enhance
countries’ ownership of their poverty strategies
This
concluding section sets out a series of suggestions on how to overcome the
ownership obstacles that remain despite the PRS approach. These address both the
external ‘top-down’ problems posed by the actions of external stakeholders,
but also things that country authorities themselves can do to produce their own
tailored and effective plans for reducing poverty.
·
Move to
a ‘Consultative Group’-style endorsement of countries’ strategies as a
first step. Moving country-donor interaction away
from requiring a priori IFI
endorsement before a poverty reduction strategy is implemented will be important
for enhancing ownership. We propose
moving instead to a Consultative Group-style type of endorsement as a first
step, where the IFIs are not the primi
inter pares amongst donors, and where the link can be made between
discussion of countries' strategies and the financing that donors are prepared
to put in.
·
Reconsider
the role of conditionality. The IFIs face the
dilemma that conditionality has largely failed to achieve the policy results
that were intended, yet they need at the same time to safeguard the use of their
resources. The response so far has mostly been to reduce the numbers of
conditions in programmes. Yet there needs to be more fundamental reflection on
the link between ownership and conditionality. While in our view conditionality
is not necessarily antipathetic to
ownership, conditionality would need to be ‘self-imposed’ for it to avoid
compromising ownership. Further, more thought needs to be put into the role of
results-based ex-post financing where
access to IFI funds would be on the basis of results in achieving a country’s
poverty reduction goals. The focus on end-results
achieved in reducing poverty is key.[21]
·
Put
everything in the publicly available poverty strategy. The
temptation to ‘top up’ the specification of proposed policy reforms in IFI
lending documentation (eg, in PRSC
documents), but without adding this additional information to the overall
poverty strategy, must be avoided. All the plans and proposed reforms must be in
the public, country-owned document, in the form of appendices if necessary, and
open for public discussion.
·
Expect countries’ strategies for poverty
reduction to be even more comprehensive than the current macro/structural/social
parameters of the current PRSP specification.
Development planning must also consider areas that are traditionally not part of
World Bank or IMF concerns. These might be purely political matters, such as
institutional reform issues (eg,
relating to the role of parliaments, or to institutionalising responsibilities
for participation). They might also be politically contentious reforms, such as
land reform, which the IFIs have avoided in the past, but which are vital for
addressing key poverty issues such as equity, security and access to productive
assets.
·
Ask for
an appendix of stakeholder comments. NGOs have
proposed the inclusion of an appendix or accompanying report to the finished
strategy that gives space to comments from non-governmental stakeholders
involved in the strategy process, including the private sector, CSOs,
faith-based groups and others. This would be an effective way of allowing the
international community to assess how participatory the process had been, and to
what extent proposals from non-governmental stakeholders had been incorporated.
·
Address
the HIPC Initiative-PRSP process tension. Whilst
it is now too late to address the problems inherent in the PRSP Initiative
approach, we feel that the ‘flexible PRSP’ approach agreed at the 2000
Annual Meetings should be extended. It was decided then that, in the event that
a full PRSP had not been drawn up one year after the PRSP Initiative, a
‘progress report’ would be an acceptable basis for continued IFI lending and
continued interim debt relief under the HIPC Initiative.
·
Tie
donor assistance more closely to countries’ plans.
Bilateral donors should go further in integrating their development assistance
with a country’s poverty strategy and in collaborating more closely with each
other. One important step for enhancing ownership is to move towards budgetary
support. In addition, a key area to which the European Commission[22]
for example attaches great importance is the strengthening of institutional
capacity in developing countries.[23]
·
And a
final proposal: Drop the ‘PRSP’ label. We have
been careful here not to talk about ‘PRS’ processes or ‘PRSPs’ in a
generic fashion, and have confined use of those terms only to discussion of the
specific papers being prepared for endorsement by the IFIs’ boards. In future,
it would be better to talk about a country’s strategy for poverty reduction,
or plans for sustainable development, or whatever the country authorities
themselves want to call their documents. This would be a simple gesture
underlining the fact that ownership of countries’ strategies should be
transferred to countries themselves. They should be free to call them what they
want.
Notes:
[1]
For more information on the PRSP approach, see EURODAD’s paper “An
Independent Guide to PRSP”
http://www.eurodad.org/2poverty/indexpoverty1.htm
[2]
For discussions in ‘official’ documents see, eg, External Evaluation of
ESAF, IMF 1998.
[3]
PRSP Processes in Eight African
Countries Initial Impacts and Potential for Institutionalisation, paper
prepared for WIDER Development Conference on Debt Relief, Helsinki 17-18
August 2001, David Booth, ODI, p. 12.
[4]
‘Internal’ and ‘external’ ownership are not necessarily separate
entities: ownership could be analysed along any number of different lines.
The distinction between ‘external’ and ‘internal’ ownership is used
here simply for ease of analysis.
[5]
PRSP Processes in Eight African
Countries, op cit, p. 6.
[6]
Aid and Reform in Africa: Lessons from
Ten Case Studies, World Bank March 2001
www.worldbank.org/research/aid/africa/draftsum.pdf, p. 32.
[7]
EURODAD Poverty and Structural Adjustment update Spring Meetings 2001
www.eurodad.org/2poverty/indexpoverty1.htm
[8]
For example, “the ruling elites
found it convenient to perpetuate low literacy rates. The lower the
proportion of lower and literate people, the lower the probability that the
ruling elite could be displaced”, Hussain 1999, quoted by Easterly
www.worldbank.org/research/growth/pdfiles/five_myths.ppt
[9]
PRSP Processes in Eight African
Countries, op cit, p. 7.
[10]
When the PRSP approach was first adopted, there was much theoretical
discussion about what would happen in the event that a country embarked on a
controversial reform path, and whether or not the IFIs would endorse the
strategy. With hindsight, this debate was a red herring, as the key concern
for country authorities has of course been continued access to donor
funding. To this end, there has been little willingness to ‘rock the PRSP
boat’.
[11]
Poverty-Reducing Institutional Change
and PRSP Processes: The Ghana case, Tony Killick, ODI, August 2001, p.
11.
[13]
Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper;
Input from Civil Society Organisations, TCDD/PRSP Coalition, March 2000,
p. 5.
[14]
The PRSP process in Uganda, Zie
Garuyo, Uganda Debt Network 2001, p. 19.
[15]
Donors and Government Marginalise
Civil Society in the CG Process, Feminist Activism Coalition Tanzania,
(FEMACT) September 2001.
[16]
PRSP Processes in Eight African
Countries, op cit, p. 11.
[17]
PRSP in Malawi – Progress Report and
Recommendations, Malawi Economic Justice Network, April 2001, p. 21.
[18]
Building Institutions for Markets, World
Development Report, World Bank, 2002 www.worldbank.org/
[19]
PRSP in Malawi, April 2001, op
cit, p. 20.
[20]
PRSP Processes in Eight African
Countries, op cit, p. 9.
[21]
There are of course practical issues with how to measure results, but this
also holds true for current practice.
[22]
EC Delegations, with the support of headquarters, are trying to identify a
possible role for EC-financed technical assistance including training in the
process of strengthening institutions and capacity-building.
[23]
Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers:
Guidance Notes, European Commission DG Development, August 2000, p. 5.
|