2007
Population trends in the 21st century: Demographic bonus or demographic anchor?
Daniel Ciganda
Social Watch Secretariat
Predictions of an acceleration in the ageing of the population over coming years have supported arguments for social security reforms in many countries, in general under a cloud of pessimistic forecasts about the future impact of ageing on pension systems. However, changes in the age structure of the population produce quite complex effects that entail not only problems but also opportunities. The utilization of these opportunities will not be automatic but will depend on the adoption of appropriate policies.
Just as
urbanization and the accelerated decline in fertility were the demographic
processes which characterized the 20th century, the 21st century faces
challenges posed by two demographic phenomena to which analysts and those
responsible for designing policy are devoting a large part of their attention:
population ageing and migration.
As a result of migratory movements during the 20th century, there are now 191
million people (3% of the world’s population) living outside their country of
origin. In the first few years of this century alone, between 2000 and 2005, the
more developed regions received 13.1 million immigrants from the less developed
regions. The political, social and
economic consequences of these movements have become one of the central issues
on the agendas of the governments of the countries affected, either by the
exodus or by the massive influx of migrants.
Although it is perhaps more silent, the other demographic process with profound
present and future consequences for the possibilities of development of
contemporary societies is population ageing. United Nations projections predict
that by 2050 the number of people in the world over the age of 60 – which is
currently approximately 700 million – will reach two billion. When that
happens, the older adult population will exceed the population of children under
14 for the first time in the history of humankind.
Although at present ageing is more marked in developed countries, the less
developed regions are also undergoing accelerated changes. While it took the
countries of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 75 years
to double the percentage of persons aged 65 and over (from 7% to 14%), it is
predicted that in countries with medium and low incomes, the transition will be
effected in 30 years.
It is fairly obvious that such transformations will have profound effects on
social institutions in general and on social security in particular. However,
the way in which these effects will make themselves felt is less clear.
Transitions and opportunities
The changes in the age structure of the population resulting from the first
demographic transition and their potential effects on economic growth have been
widely analyzed. Basically, this process may be described as follows: the
passage from conditions of high mortality and high fertility to those of low
mortality and low fertility brings about a series of changes which may be
classified in three stages. At first, the population is ‘rejuvenated’
through an increase in the proportion of children, since it is infants and
children who most benefit from the decline in mortality rates. During the second
stage, the proportion of children begins to diminish and that of adults and
older adults increases as fertility continues to decline. After a period of low
fertility and low mortality, the proportion of both children and of economically
active adults diminishes and the process of population ageing begins.
The possibilities for development which emerge in the second stage – when the
proportion of active adults is significantly greater than that of children and
the elderly – have been labelled a ‘demographic bonus’ or ‘demographic
window of opportunity’. The increase in the working-age population should have
positive consequences for the economy, not only due to the growth of per capita
GDP but also to a greater collection of taxes. Essentially, this stage in
demographic transition is a period of opportunities; it does not automatically
lead to greater growth or development, but it could if the necessary measures
and policies are implemented.
Although this window of opportunity is already closed in regions where
development is more advanced, Latin America and the Caribbean and Asia are at a
stage of the transition where they could still take advantage of these
favourable conditions. In several African countries the situation is somewhat
more complex, since the transition to lower mortality rates has been interrupted
by the incidence of HIV/AIDS.
However, as several of this year’s Social Watch national reports show, the
majority of these countries do not enjoy the necessary conditions with regard to
education and employment to allow them to take advantage of the opportunities
offered by the current active/passive population ratio.
Those responsible for designing public policies are rarely heard stressing the
need to create the employment conditions necessary to benefit from this window
of opportunity. Far more common are the pessimistic predictions of the future
effects of population ageing. The prospect (or concrete experience) of
demographic ageing processes has sparked concerns over the viability of health
care and social security systems. In many countries, these concerns have been
used to justify reforms of systems based on intergenerational solidarity and
their replacement with systems based on personal savings.
According to the Social Watch Italy report, for example: “The need for drastic
reform of the public and compulsory pension system due to its financial
unsustainability is an issue that began to have major public resonance at the
beginning of the 1990s. There are basically three factors used as ‘proof’ of
this necessity: serious accounting imbalances in the Italian Institute of Social
Security (INPS), population ageing, and the forthcoming retirement of the
so-called ‘baby boom’
generation.”
However, the arguments behind most social security system reforms disregard the
fact that any kind of system requires economic growth to make it sustainable.
Moreover, to consider the effects of ageing exclusively as a ‘burden’ is to
forget that the increase in life expectancy goes hand in hand with an increase
in years of a healthy and active life. Nor are there valid arguments to back the
claim that an increase in productivity cannot compensate for the greater cost of
the pension system – especially since this has been the case until now in the
developed countries. As underlined by the Social Watch Spain report: “In spite of the frequent predictions that the
pension system is headed for collapse, the fact is that since 1998, the Spanish
social security system has actually accumulated a surplus.”
Furthermore, some researchers have suggested the possibility of a ‘second
demographic bonus’ linked to the process of ageing. The basic idea is that,
provided that the increase of the retirement age entails greater savings on the
part of individuals, the state and/or companies, subsequent investment of that
capital in order to finance consumption during the non-active years will cause
the economy to grow faster than if those savings did not exist.
Although this is an interesting idea inasmuch as it shows a possible positive
effect of ageing, in current conditions the saving possibilities of most of the
world’s population are more than limited. In fact, more realistic projections
regarding private saving capacity have served to back the call for implementing
other solutions, such as a global old-age pension. “There is still significant
pensioner poverty today but matters will become much worse by 2030 and 2040 as
already enacted reductions in entitlement come into effect. Supposedly private
savings, and new efforts by the financial services industry, will make up for
this shortfall, but exorbitant charges and tempting information gaps between
supplier and customer virtually rule this out, as official projections
themselves reveal. If private financing of pensions fails in the rich countries
because of cost rations and unequal information, its contribution in poor
countries will be even more disappointing.”
However, the limitations of private savings do not appear to be the only
difficulty with regard to mitigating the effects of decreased income after
retirement. The way in which reforms have been undertaken is also problematic,
as pointed out by the Social Watch Malta report: “The longevity risk is shifted squarely to the
shoulders of individual contributors of the same generation and not borne by the
state, since the move to a direct contribution scheme shifts the financial risk
of changing economic and demographic factors from the state to the individual.
Taken together, all these measures tend to disadvantage those with low lifetime
earnings...”
None of these arguments attempt to deny the need to reform the health care or
social security systems, but rather to challenge the arguments that focus
exclusively on predicted shortages and their purported effect on financial
sustainability. In other words, the ability to forecast future scenarios should
not lead to the adoption of desperate measures based on the most pessimistic
predictions, but to a search for viable and solidly grounded alternatives that
create the conditions to take advantage of the opportunities offered by the
first or second ‘demographic bonus’.
The most effective measures for achieving this aim will depend not only on the
particular stage of the demographic transition in which individual countries or
regions find themselves, but also on a series of contextual factors. Therefore,
any proposals must be based on detailed analyses of specific national and
regional conditions, such as those presented in the national reports in this
year’s Social Watch report. In short, while the prediction of medium and
long-term population trends is a fundamental input for planning, whether these
trends are translated into development opportunities or obstacles ultimately
depends on the policies adopted.
Notes:
International Migration 2006 (poster). United Nations Department of
Economic and Social Affairs (DESA), Population Division.
World population prospects: the 2004
revision. United Nations, DESA, Population Division, 2005.
Sigg, R.
(2007). “A Global Overview on Social Security in the Age of Longevity”. In United Nations Expert Group Meeting on Social and Economic Implications
of Changing Population Age Structure. United Nations, New York.
In order to shed light on these issues and adopt measures to address the current
and future situation of older adults, some voices have begun to call for a UN
Convention on Ageing, taking into account the results of the Second World
Assembly on Ageing. See the chapter by Susanne Paul and Alischa Kugel in this
Report.
See the box on HIV/AIDS in Asia, Africa and Latin America in this Report.
For a detailed
analysis, on the role played by the World Bank as principal promoter of these
reforms see the chapter by Antonio Tricarico in this Report.
Similar
situations are described in other national reports, such as those from Malta,
Spain and Germany, where the effects of ageing have been clearly perceptible for
a number of years.
Mason, A.
(2007). “Demographic transition and demographic dividends in Developed and
Developing countries”. In United Nations
Expert Group Meeting on Social and Economic Implications of Changing Population
Age Structure. United Nations, New York.
Blackburn, R. (2007). Building
Equality from the Ground Up: An
Outline Proposal for a Global Pension (and Youth Grant). In Lawrence & Wishart,
<www.lwbooks.co.uk/journals/articles/blackburn207.html>.
|