2000
Capital controls in Malaysia
Martin Khor
On September 1st 1998, Malaysia became the first Asian country affected by the economic crisis to announce selective exchange and capital controls in an attempt to lay the ground for a recovery programme. Until recently, capital controls were a taboo subject. With its action, Malaysia broke the policy taboo. Only a week earlier, the American economist Paul Krugman had broken the intellectual taboo by advocating that Asian countries adopt exchange controls. The Malaysian moves involved fixing the local currency to the US dollar, stopping the overseas trade in ringgit currency and other ringgit assets, restricting the amount of currency and investments that residents can take abroad, and requiring a minimum one-year “stay period” for foreign portfolio funds. (The last measure has since been converted to an exit tax.) The measures were aimed at reducing the country's exposure to financial speculators and the global financial turmoil.
The Malaysian policy package included:
·
The official fixing of the ringgit at 3.80 to the US
dollar, thus removing or greatly reducing the role of market forces in
determining the day-to-day level of the local currency (the ringgit's value in
relation to currencies other than the dollar will still fluctuate according to
their own rates against the dollar). This
measure largely removes uncertainties regarding the future level of the ringgit.
·
Measures relating to the local stock market, including
the closure of secondary markets so that trade can be done only via the Kuala
Lumpur Stock Exchange (this is to prevent speculation or manipulation from
outside the country), and the requirement that non-residents purchasing local
shares have to retain the shares or the proceeds from sale for a year from the
purchase date (this is to reduce foreign speculative short-term trade in local
shares). The one-year requirement
has since been replaced by a graduated exit tax on the invested amount (for
funds invested before the September 1998 controls) and a tax on profits and
capital gains (for funds entering after February 15th 1999 and staying less than
a year).
·
Measures to reduce and eliminate the international
trade in ringgit, by bringing back to the country ringgit-denominated financial
assets such as cash and savings deposits via the non-recognition or
non-acceptance of such assets in the country after a one-month dateline.
(Permission will, however, be given under certain conditions.)
·
Resident travellers are allowed to import ringgit notes
up to RM1,000 only and any amount of foreign currencies, and to export only up
to RM1,000 and foreign currencies only up to RM10,000 equivalent.
·
Except for payments for imports of goods and services,
residents are freely allowed to make payments to non-residents only up to
RM10,000 or its equivalent in foreign currency
(previously the limit was set at RM100,000).
*Any
form of investments abroad by residents and payments under a guarantee for
non-trade purposes require approval.
*Prescribed
manner of payment for exports will be in foreign currency only (previously it
was allowed to be in foreign currency or ringgit from an External Account).
*Domestic
credit facilities to non-resident correspondent banks and non-resident
stockbroking companies are no longer allowed (previously domestic credit up to
RM5 million was allowed).
*Residents
require prior approval to make payments to non-residents for purposes of
investing abroad for amounts exceeding RM10,000 equivalent in foreign exchange.
*Residents
are not allowed to obtain ringgit credit facilities from non-residents.
·
Measures imposing conditions on the operations and
transfers of funds in external accounts: transfers between external accounts
require prior approval for any amount (previously freely allowed); transfers
from external accounts to resident accounts will require approval;
and sources of funding external accounts are limited to proceeds from sale of
ringgit instruments and other assets in Malaysia, salaries, interest and
dividend and sale of foreign currency.
In general, the ringgit is still freely
convertible to foreign currencies for trade (export receipts and import
payments), inward foreign direct investment, and repatriation of profit by
non-residents. Convertibility up to
a certain limit is also allowed for certain other purposes, such as financing
children's education abroad. But convertibility for autonomous capital movements
for several purposes not directly related to trade will be limited.
The rationale for the move was explained by
the Malaysian Prime Minister Datuk Seri Dr Mahathir Mohamed as a last resort. “We had asked the international agencies to regulate
currency trading but they did not care, so we ourselves have to regulate our own
currency,” he said in a media interview in September 1998. “If the
international community agrees to regulate currency trading and limit the range
of currency fluctuations and enables countries to grow again, then we can return
to the floating exchange rate system. But
now we can see the damage this system has done throughout the world. It has
destroyed the hard work of countries to cater to the interests of speculators as
if their interests are so important that millions of people must suffer. This is
regressive.”
Explaining the move to make offshore use of
the ringgit invalid, Mahathir said normally it was offshore ringgit that were
used by speculators to manipulate the currency.
The speculators hold the ringgit in foreign banks abroad and have
corresponding amounts in banks in Malaysia.
Mahathir also said that with the introduction
of exchange controls, it would be possible to cut the link between interest rate
and the exchange rate. “We can reduce interest rates without speculators
devaluing our currency. Our
companies can revive. If our
currency is revalued upwards, the companies can buy imports as they don't have
to pay so much.”
He said the Malaysian measures were aimed at
putting a spanner in the works of speculators, to take speculators out of
currency trade. He added the period
of highest economic growth was during the Bretton Woods fixed exchange system.
But the free market system that followed the Bretton Woods system has
failed because of abuses. “There are signs that people are now losing faith in
this free market system, but some countries benefit from the abuses, their
people make more money, so they don't see why the abuses should be curbed.”
Brief
analysis of the measures
The measures constitute a bold attempt to
give the economy a reasonable chance to recover. By restricting the availability
of ringgit in offshore markets and restricting the international trade in
ringgit, the measures are aimed at greatly reducing the conditions and
opportunities for speculators to make profits on fluctuations in the ringgit's
value. The move to have the ringgit's rate fixed by the financial authorities,
rather than by the market, has also restored greater financial stability by
reducing the uncertain conditions under which businesses and consumers now have
to operate.
Instead of fixing the exchange rate through a
Currency Board system (where money supply and domestic interest rates are
determined by the foreign reserves and inflows and outflows of funds), Malaysia
has chosen the route of controlling the flows of ringgit and foreign exchange.
The advantage of this approach is that it allows the government greater degrees
of freedom to determine domestic policy, particularly in influencing domestic
interest rates. The government can now reduce interest rates without being
overly constrained by the reaction of the market and by fears of the ringgit
falling. Since the introduction of the measures, interest rates have fallen by
about five percentage points. This
has eased the debt servicing burden of businesses and consumers (especially
house buyers), and the financial position of banks.
The decision to make ringgit held abroad
invalid after one month is meant to encourage an inflow of ringgit to return to
the country. It has also dried up
sources of ringgit held abroad that speculators borrow from to manipulate the
ringgit, for example by “selling short.”
No doubt some Malaysians who hold ringgit accounts abroad, or who travel
frequently and who need to transfer funds abroad,
may suffer some inconveniences. But
these personal sacrifices can be taken as contributions to generating some
conditions that are needed to get a serious recovery going.
The exchange control measures are a response
to the basic causes of the crisis afflicting both the country and the region. The crisis began with funds being allowed to freely move in
and out of the affected countries. Those
countries had recently liberalised their financial systems, allowing locals and
foreigners alike to freely convert foreign currency into local currency, and
vice versa.
This currency convertibility was allowed not
only to finance current transactions of trade and direct investment (which in
the past had also been permitted), but also in the capital account, ie, for short-term flows such as investment in the stock markets,
loans from and to abroad, and remittances to abroad by individuals and companies
for savings or property purchases overseas. By introducing this “capital
account convertibility”, the countries exposed themselves to autonomous
inflows and outflows of funds by foreigners and locals, subjecting their local
currency to speculation as well as exchange-rate volatility.
The crisis was sparked by speculation and a
stampede of foreign funds moving out, followed shortly by locals also sending
their money abroad, whilst the local currencies fell sharply. Now that the
countries are in deep recession, capital account convertibility is causing
another equally vexing problem. It is preventing them from taking policies they
need for recovery.
A major policy needed is to lower interest
rates (to relieve consumers and companies from their heavy debt service burden)
and increase spending (so that there is more demand for businesses and incomes
for workers). Countries are
constrained from this line of action, however, because speculators may again
attack the local currency. Also, some residents may be tempted to send more of
their savings abroad in search of higher interest rates. The possibility of
funds exiting in an environment of free capital account convertibility of the
local currency thus puts a damper on measures that are needed for recovery.
Therefore, one logical move would be for the
affected countries to partly re-impose some control over the convertibility of
the local currency. This could reduce the conditions in which currency
speculators can profitably operate, reduce the exit of funds and discourage the
inflows of undesirable forms of short-term capital.
Many observers point to China and India as
examples of countries that have not been subjected to volatile capital flows and
currency instability because they do not allow full convertibility of their
currencies. The lesson is that developing
countries that want to shield themselves from externally-generated financial
crises should retain (or regain) some controls over the convertibility of their
currency.
The option of reintroducing some capital
controls has till recently not been openly discussed, however, because it is
considered a “taboo” subject. The prevailing ideology held and spread by the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the Group of Seven rich countries is that
countries should liberalise their capital account, and that countries that have
done so will suffer damage if they re-impose controls.
Policy-makers in the affected countries are
worried that even to discuss the advantages of capital control means
black-listing by the IMF, the rich countries and financial speculators. By
keeping silent, their countries will continue to be subjected to the views and
interests of “market players”, suffer the consequences of a relatively high
interest rate policy, and be prevented from speedy recovery.
Overcoming
academic taboo
On the academic level, the taboo against
capital controls was broken in August 1998 when the Massachusetts Institute of
Technology (MIT) economist Paul Krugman advocated that Asian governments should
re-impose capital controls as the only way out of their crisis. In his Fortune
article, entitled “Saving Asia: it's time to get RADICAL”, Krugman agrees
with the IMF critics that high interest rates imposed by the IMF would cause
even healthy banks and companies to collapse.
Thus, there is a strong case for countries to keep interest rates low and
try to keep their real economies growing. However, says Krugman, the problem is
that the original objection to interest rate reductions still stands, that the
region's currencies could again go into free fall if the interest rate is not
high enough.
Krugman said there is a way out, “but it is
a solution so unfashionable, so stigmatised, that hardly anyone has dared to
suggest it. The unsayable words are
exchange controls.” Exchange
controls, he adds, used to be the standard response of countries with balance of
payments crises. “Exporters were
required to sell their foreign-currency earnings to the government at a fixed
exchange rate; that currency would in turn be sold at the same rate for approved
payments to foreigners, basically for imports and debt service. Whilst some
countries tried to make other foreign-exchange transactions illegal, other
countries allowed a parallel market. Either
way, once the system was in place, a country didn't have to worry that cutting
interest rates would cause the currency to plunge. Maybe the parallel exchange
rate would sink, but that wouldn't affect the prices of imports or the balance
sheets of companies and banks.”
Asking why China has not been so badly hit as
its neighbours, Krugman answers that China “has been able to cut, not raise,
interest rates in this crisis, despite maintaining a fixed exchange rate; and
the reason it is able to do that is that it has an inconvertible currency, that
is to say, exchange controls. Those controls are often evaded, and they are a
source of lots of corruption, but they still give China a degree of policy
leeway that the rest of Asia desperately wishes it had.
As
more economists like Krugman speak up, capital controls are being recognised as
a respectable option for governments wanting an effective policy instrument to
prevent further financial turbulence. After
the announcement of the Malaysian measures, Krugman published an open letter to
the Malaysian Prime Minister stating that he fervently hoped the dramatic policy
move pays off. He warned, however,
that these controls are risky with no guarantee for success.
He gave four guidelines: that the controls should aim at minimal
disruption of business; that they be temporary; that the currency should not be
pegged at too high a level; and that they serve to aid reforms and not be an
alternative.
UNCTAD's
advocacy of using capital controls
The need for developing counties to make use
of capital controls to prevent and manage financial crises has also been
stressed by UNCTAD.
In fact, UNCTAD has been the international agency that has consistently
been warning about the dangers of financial liberalisation and the risks posed
by a policy of allowing freedom for the inflows and outflows of funds.
UNCTAD's Trade
and Development Report 1998 makes a central point that to
protect themselves against international financial instability, developing
countries need to have capital controls, since these constitute a proven
technique for dealing with volatile capital flows. The report comes to this
conclusion after surveying several other measures (such as more disclosure of
information and greater banking regulation) that have been proposed by the
industrial countries and the International Monetary Fund. The agency finds these
proposals to have merit but inadequate to deal with the present and future
crises. It therefore stresses that developing countries should be allowed to
introduce capital controls, as these are “an indispensable part of their
armoury of measures for the purpose of protection against international
financial instability.”
The Report notes that good economic
fundamentals, effective financial regulation and good corporate governance are
needed to avoid financial crises, but by themselves they are not sufficient. Experience
shows that to avoid these crises, a key role is played by capital controls and
other measures that influence external borrowing, lending and asset holding.
Control on capital flows are imposed for two reasons: firstly, as part of
macroeconomic management (to reinforce or substitute for monetary and fiscal
measures) and secondly to attain long-term national development goals (such as
ensuring residents’ capital is locally invested or that certain types of
activities are reserved for residents).
Contrary to the belief that capital controls
are rare, taboo or practised only by a few countries that are somehow
“anti-market”, the reality is that these measures have been very widely
used. UNCTAD notes that they have been a “pervasive feature” of the last few
decades. In early post-war years, capital controls for macroeconomic reasons
were generally imposed on outflows of funds as part of policies dealing with
balance of payments difficulties and to avoid or reduce devaluations.
Rich and poor countries alike also used
controls on capital inflows for longer-term development reasons. When freer
capital movements were allowed from the 1960s onwards, large capital inflows
posed problems for rich countries such as Germany, Holland and Switzerland.
They imposed controls such as limits on non-residents' purchase of local
debt securities and on bank deposits of non-residents.
More recently, some developing countries
facing problems due to large capital inflows also resorted to capital controls.
For example, when faced with a surge of short-term capital inflows, Malaysia in
January 1994 imposed several: banks were subjected to a ceiling on their
external liabilities not related to trade or investment; residents were barred
from selling short-term monetary instruments to non-residents; banks had to
deposit at no interest in the central bank moneys in ringgit accounts owned by
foreign banks; and banks were restricted in outright forward and swap
transactions they could engage in with foreigners.
These measures were gradually removed from 1995 onwards.
When Chile was faced with large capital
inflows in the early 1990s, it took measures to slow short-term inflows and even
to encourage certain types of outflows. The
main step was that foreign loans entering Chile were subjected to a reserve
requirement of 20% (later raised to 30%). In
other words, a certain percentage of each loan had to be deposited at the
central bank for a year, without being paid any interest. Also to prevent
excessive inflows, Brazil in mid-1994 imposed controls such as an increase in
the tax paid by Brazilian firms on bonds issued abroad, a tax on foreigners'
investment in the stock market, and an increase in tax on foreign purchases of
domestic fixed-income investments. When the Czech Republic faced large inflows
in 1994/95, it imposed a tax of 0.25% on foreign-exchange transactions with
banks and limits on (and the need for official approval for) short-term
borrowing abroad by banks and other firms. Besides the specific cases above, the
UNCTAD Report also lists examples of capital controls on inflows as well as
outflows.
Controls on inflows of foreign direct
investment and portfolio equity investment may take the form of licensing,
ceilings on foreign equity participation in local firms, official permission for
international equity issues, differential regulations applying to local and
foreign firms regarding establishment and permissible operations and various
kinds of two-tier markets. Some of these controls can also be imposed on capital
inflows associated with debt securities, including bonds.
Such inflows can be subject to special taxes or be limited to
transactions carried out through a two-tier market. Ceilings (as low as zero)
may apply to non-residents' holdings of debt issues of firms and government; or
foreigners may need approval to buy such issues.
Foreigners can also be excluded from auctions for government bonds and
paper.
UNCTAD also lists other controls commonly
used to restrict external borrowings from banks. They include: a special reserve
requirement concerning liabilities to non-residents; forbidding banks to pay
interest on deposits of non-residents or even requiring a commission on such
deposits; taxing foreign borrowing (to eliminate the margin between local and
foreign interest rates); and requiring firms to deposit cash at the central bank
amounting to a proportion of their external borrowing.
As for controls on capital outflows, they can
include controls over outward transactions for direct and portfolio equity
investment by residents as well as foreigners. Restrictions on repatriation of
capital by foreigners can include specifying a period before such repatriation
is allowed, and regulations that phase the repatriation according to the
availability of foreign exchange or to the need to maintain an orderly market
for the country's currency. Residents may be restricted as to their holdings of
foreign stocks, either directly or through limits on the permissible portfolios
of the country's investment funds. Two-tier exchange rates may also be used to
restrict residents’ foreign investment by requiring that capital transactions
be undertaken through a market in which a less favourable rate prevails,
compared to the rate for current transactions. Some of these techniques are also
used for purchases of debt securities issued abroad and for other forms of
lending abroad. Bank deposits
abroad by residents can also be restricted by law.
UNCTAD says recent financial crises and
frequent use of capital controls by countries to contain the effects of swings
in capital flows point to the case for continuing to give governments the
autonomy to control transactions. It questions recent moves in the IMF to
restrict the autonomy or freedom of countries to control flows.
Ways have not yet been found at a global
level to eliminate the cross-border transmission of financial shocks and crises
due to global financial integration and capital movements.
Thus, concludes UNCTAD, for the foreseeable future, countries must be
allowed the flexibility to introduce capital control measures, instead of new
obligations being imposed on these countries to further liberalise capital
movements through them.
Conclusion
Given an international environment of big
financial players with huge blocs of money for speculation and investment,
financially small countries are now subjected to great volatility and financial
and economic danger. For instance,
the LTCM affair revealed that a hedge fund with USD 4-5 billion equity could
manage to raise so much credit that the banks had USD 200 billion exposure to
it. Few governments can withstand a determined bid by a few big
hedge funds to speculate on their currencies and financial markets.
And besides the hedge funds, there are other gigantic investment funds
(such as mutual and pension funds) as well as investment banks, commercial
banks, insurance companies etc.
The almost total freedom given to
international investors and speculators has wreaked financial and now economic
and social chaos. The time has now
come to regulate these big players. But there are serious doubts whether there
is the political will to act, as the financial institutions and those that own
and manage them are very powerful and it is in the vested interest of
politicians and their parties to cater to these powerful institutions.
Developing countries need to protect
themselves from the free flow of funds. Capital controls are thus a necessary
part of economic instruments that must be an option. In these days of financial
turbulence, they may even be a necessary option. This does not mean that capital
controls by themselves are a panacea or “magic bullet”.
They should be accompanied, eg,
by an international mechanism for debt standstill to help seriously indebted
countries.
Moreover, there are weaknesses and loopholes
in capital controls, such as leakages through transfer pricing mechanisms, false
invoicing, possible black markets, etc.
Also, capital controls should not merely be a shield for a country to protect
itself from having to carry out changes and reforms made necessary by the
financial crisis, or reforms that are structurally needed for the longer run.
The
success of efforts to revive a financially viable economy will also depend
greatly on the effectiveness, efficiency and fairness (in burden sharing) of
recapitalisation, restructuring and reforms in the financial institutions and
corporations. It will also depend on the right mix of monetary and fiscal
policies that can spur recovery without causing greater financial or economic
burdens on ordinary citizens, especially the poor. In other words, capital
controls are a necessary but not sufficient condition to protect a country from
unresolvable crisis and to enable conditions for recovery.
They have to be accompanied by other measures.
The
fact that there are weaknesses in capital controls, and that other measures are
also needed, does not make capital controls a wrong or evil policy option, as
some opponents of capital controls appear to portray them. Total freedom for
capital flows is a principle championed by the big financial players and
institutions that stand to gain from extreme financial liberalisation. Capital
controls to limit such freedom are needed from an objective point of view and
from the viewpoint of ordinary citizens who need to be protected from predatory
speculation and from economic chaos.
United Nations Conference
on Trade and Development.
|