2006
Reclaiming development: streamline the Bretton Woods institutions
Celine Tan [1]
Third World Network
The Bretton Woods institutions – the World Bank and the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) – are considered “specialized agencies” under
the Charter of the United Nations (UN) in 1945 and the terms of their
relationship with the UN are spelt out in respective “relationship agreements”
entered into between the Bank and the IMF and the UN. Central to these
agreements between these international financial institutions (IFIs) and the UN
are clauses which respect the demarcation of roles between the respective
organizations and the affirmation of the autonomy of IFIs in matters within
their specific jurisdictions.
This decision to retain the organizational independence of
the Bretton Woods institutions from the UN system, and the maintenance of their
different governance structures favouring a small cartel of major industrialized
countries, has had significant implications for global economic policymaking and
international economic and financial cooperation, as well as on the social and
economic development of developing countries. It has also largely prevented the
institutions from undertaking the tasks they were originally created for – to
provide for a stable and orderly international trade and financial system and to
facilitate reconstruction and development.
Any reform of the multilateral governance institutions,
including the current ongoing discussions on UN reform, must therefore include a
reform of multilateral financial institutions to ensure the creation of truly
international financial and economic governance organizations which better
represent and service the interests of all member states and enable the better
coordination among existing multilateral institutions to do the same. These
institutions must also be subjected to the overarching universal principles
which underlie all multilateral processes of decision-making which encompass not
only the principle of equality among states but also a respect for human rights
and the right to sustainable development.
An affront to the principle of sovereign equality and
the erosion of multilateralism in global economic governance
The constitutional frameworks of the Bretton Woods
institutions are an affront to the principle of equality among states and their
operational practice over the years since their inception reflects a progressive
erosion of the principle of multilateralism in international affairs. Although
both institutions justify their autonomy from the United Nations system on the
grounds that each of them is “required to function as an independent
international organization”,
neither of these institutions are truly “independent” nor “international” in
character.
The governance structure of the Bretton Woods institutions
is inherently asymmetrical in favour of developed countries and this asymmetry
has been exacerbated over the years by both the development of the global
economy and the shift in the nature of the work programmes of both
organizations. The result is that those countries least affected by the
decisions of the World Bank and IMF have the most influence and the most
capacity to hold either institutions to account, while those who are subjected
to their policies and who form the bulk of the institutions’ operations have the
least say in how these institutions are run.
In a paradoxical twist, changes in the financial
operations of both institutions over the years have resulted in borrowing
members – the developing countries who have little power in the decision-making
processes – shouldering the bulk of the costs of administering the Bretton Woods
institutions and their activities. While the core capital of the World Bank and
the IMF relies on the financial contributions of their wealthiest shareholders –
through quota subscriptions for the IMF and paid-in and “callable” capital for
the World Bank – the current administrative costs of both institutions are now
largely financed by borrowing member states through the charges and interest on
their loan repayments and, in the case of the World Bank, their track record in
servicing their International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD)
debts which contributes to the Bank’s ratings in the international capital
markets (Mohammed, 2004).
There has also been a creeping “bilateralism” which has
increased the control of specific developed countries over the policies of these
supposedly multilateral institutions. As “a form of global collective action”,
multilateral lending is seen as a type of redistribution and instrument of
international economic cooperation in which richer states pool their resources
to provide external financing to poorer countries to prevent the negative
externalities associated with international capital market failures and to
assist in the provision of global public goods (Akyüz, 2006).
However the principle of multilateralism in the Bretton
Woods institutions have been significantly weakened since the “introduction of
donor-driven concessional windows” (Akyüz, 2006), such as the International
Development Association (IDA) (with its three-year replenishment cycle) at the
Bank and the Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility, now the Poverty Reduction
and Gross Facility (PRGF), at the IMF. These facilities require periodic
replenishments from bilateral donors, providing opportunities for these
countries to exercise leverage over the policies of the Bretton Woods
institutions outside the usual decision-making process.
Expansion of constitutional mandates and failure in
fulfilling traditional responsibilities
The administrative costs for running the World Bank and
the IMF have increased substantially in recent decades as a result of policies
pursued by their developed country members. After the collapse of the fixed
exchange rate system in 1972 and particularly since the advent of the debt
crisis in the 1980s, the World Bank and the IMF have greatly expanded the remit
of their responsibilities, extending their reach into areas which were
traditionally outside their jurisdiction while downgrading or abandoning other
aspects of their work.
One of the most fundamental aspects of the Bretton Woods
institutions ‘mission creep’ is the Bank and IMF’s shift of focus towards social
and economic development policy of developing countries, including domestic
economic regulation, trade policy, poverty alleviation, social welfare and even
environmental protection. This shift has been most pronounced for the IMF in
terms of divergence from its constitutional objectives although the World Bank’s
expansion has been more extensive in scope.
The IMF no longer plays a role in ensuring international
financial and monetary stability although the need for such a multilateral
organization has never been greater given the globalization of finance capital
and the volatility of financial flows today. The institution no longer exercises
any discipline over exchange rate policies of its member states and has no
authority over the important players in the global financial system – the
industrialized countries – whose domestic policies affect the stability of
international financial architecture more than those of the developing countries
for whom IMF regulation has been most pronounced.
The Fund’s extension of short-term current account
financing to countries experiencing financial crises has been seriously
circumscribed both by its introduction of conditionality as well as the policy
prescriptions of the adjustment programmes which accompany such financing. The
IMF’s financing operations for crisis countries have also been focused on
servicing external debt to private creditors and maintaining capital account
convertibility (Akyüz, 2005) rather than assisting countries to manage with the
social and economic repercussions of financial crises. Instead, many of the
policies instituted by the IMF through conditionality in these countries have
worsened the social and economic dislocations of the financial crisis.
Similar impacts have resulted from the Bank’s foray into
development policy lending and sectoral reform programmes which have promoted
liberalization of markets, market-based land reform, the privatization of
essential services such as health, education and water, and the elimination of
government subsidies and protection for infant industries and agricultural
sectors. This policy-based financing has provided the opposite function to the
Bank’s mandate of providing capital for reconstruction and development: they are
“fast-disbursing” loans serving primarily to meet short-term balance of payments
needs and economic restructuring purposes as opposed to long-term developmental
targets.
The Bank has also deepened its social and economic policy
work, including through revisions of Structural Adjustment Programmes (SAPs) and
other sectoral lending instruments to include emphasis on social sectors and
poverty reduction; the promotion of various financing instruments for capacity
building and technical assistance in a plethora of different issue areas; and
through its non-financing activities, such as its dissemination of research and
policy papers and consultancy work. A report by the Bretton Woods Project
estimates that “between 1997 and 2002, USD 283 million was spent on reorganising
the Bank to be a knowledge institution”, with studies indicating that “the
Bank’s analytical approaches influence policy-making across the world even if
the Bank is not involved directly” (Wilks, 2004).
Over the same period, the role of the UN economic
agencies, notably the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD),
have been progressively weakened, with these organizations’ capacity in economic
research, policy formulation and international economic negotiations eroded
through financial and other constraints and pressures brought to bear on these
agencies and their personnel by developed countries (South Centre, 1996).
These reforms have served to establish the dominance of
the Bretton Woods institutions in issues of social and economic development in
the international arena and significantly increased the influence of the Bank
and IMF in key economic (and lately, even social and political) policy decisions
in borrowing member states. The coinciding expansion of the Bretton Woods
institutions work programmes with the reduction in the UN’s role in economic
policy agenda setting represented a slow but sure “transfer of power” from the
UN agencies to the World Bank and the IMF, thereby “eroding and weakening those
organizations which were not fully under the major powers’ control”
(South Centre, 1996, emphasis added).
“Conditionality” undermines principle of national
sovereignty and non-intervention
The expansion of the nature and content of conditionality
has taken place in tandem with the expansion of the Bretton Woods institutions’
mandate. The scope of conditionality in Bank and Fund lending now encompass
conditions which are neither relevant nor critical to the purposes of the
financing or are conditions in areas which “neither the IMF nor the World Bank
has the expertise to give proper advice”, thus creating great margins for error
and negative externalities (Khor, 2001: 12). Many of these conditions erode the
policy autonomy of countries and constitute interventions in sovereign states’
domestic affairs, such as the current proliferation of “governance-related
conditionality” (GRC), most notably at the World Bank.
Conditionality has also evolved to be a default regulatory
instrument for disciplining developing countries, including prescribing social
and political reforms. Conditionality has been used as a misguided means of
ensuring compliance of World Bank and IMF borrowing countries to social and
economic development priorities, ranging from poverty reduction to gender
equity, as well as conformity with environmental norms. At the same time, these
institutions, notably the World Bank, have failed to comply with internationally
agreed standards of protection for social, political and economic rights, and
environmental standards through their lending practices.
The use of conditionality in this manner is at odds with
the Bank’s own constitutional prohibition against political interference in
borrowing member states.
This practice is also an affront to the principles of international economic
relations as enshrined in the 1974 UN General Assembly Resolution 3281 on the
Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States, one of the fundamental norms of
international law. Chapter 1 of the Charter stipulates international economic
and political relations should be governed, inter alia, by respect for
the sovereignty, territorial integrity and political independence of states and
the principle of non-intervention.
Meanwhile Chapter II of the Charter affirms the “sovereign
and inalienable right” of states to choose their own economic, cultural and
political system without outside interference (Article 1) as well as the right
to “freely exercise full permanent sovereignty, including possession, use and
disposal, over all its wealth, natural resources and economic activities”
(Article 2(1)). These represent rights of their member states that the Bretton
Woods institutions should respect, as the institutions are “specialized
agencies” under the Charter of the United Nations.
The Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States also
provides that in efforts to fulfil their primary responsibility to economic,
social and cultural development of their peoples, “each State has the right and
the responsibility to chose its means and goals of development” (Chapter 2,
Article 7) while the 1986 UN General Assembly Resolution 41/128 on the
Declaration on the Right to Development provides that “States have the right and
the duty to formulate appropriate national development policies” and “the
primary responsibility for the creation of national and international conditions
favourable to the realization of the right to development” (Articles 2(3) &
3(1)).
The Bretton Woods institutions pay little credence to such
international norms in the design and implementation of their conditionalities.
The content of Bank and Fund conditionality has been based on the policies of
the Washington Consensus which are premised on fiscal austerity and restrictive
monetary policies, the liberalization of capital flows, trade liberalization,
deregulation and privatization. These policies have generally followed a pattern
of “one-size fits all” or a “boilerplate template” in which one set of policies
are applied to the vast majority of countries without due regard for individual
circumstances. The practice of conditionality has therefore undermined the
domestic policy space of borrowing governments and curtailed the right of these
countries to regulate their economies.
Need for reform and revitalization
The existence of the Bretton Woods institutions with their
asymmetrical governance and administrative framework existing in concert with
the UN and UN agencies created specifically for social and economic development
– such as the UN Conference on Trade and Development, and the United Nations
Development Programme – has provided a convenient alternative forum for the
discussion of issues and implementation of policies of which the more equitable
decision-making framework of the UN system have proven unconducive to the
interests of the major political powers.
There is therefore a need to both reform the
Bretton Woods institutions and reinvigorate the economic role of
the UN in order to ensure sustainable development and to achieve the objectives
of the Millennium Development Goals. Four recommendations can be put forward in
this regard:
Reforming the governance structure of the
World Bank and the IMF to ensure representativeness and accountability.
There has to be a fundamental overhaul of the archaic
governance framework of these institutions predicated upon an outdated post-war
model which no longer reflects the developments in the global economy today and
which skews decision-making control in favour of the economically powerful at
the expense of the economically weak. Developing countries must be given greater
voice and representation at the Bank and the Fund.
Streamlining the Bretton Woods institutions
and scaling them down to their original mandate.
The current workload of the World Bank and the IMF is too broad and too
intrusive and the administration of their many activities unwieldy and costly.
Streamlining the institutions so that they return to their original mandates of
facilitating a stable international trade and financial system and providing
financing for development would ensure greater efficiency and effectiveness of
these institutions and restore policy autonomy to borrowing countries.
Revitalising the role of the United Nations
economic and social development agencies. The
reduction in the scope of work of the Bretton Woods institutions should also be
accompanied by the revitalising of the work of the United Nations agencies and
other UN “specialized agencies” in the area of international economic
cooperation and domestic economic and social development. This would not only
reduce the influence of the powerful developed countries but also the influence
of the pervasive institutional ideology of the Washington Consensus prevalent at
the World Bank and IMF.
Removing the regulatory role of the Bretton
Woods institutions and subjecting them to UN scrutiny.
The application of policy conditionality as a means of
achieving internationally agreed social and development objectives, but
especially, global environmental norms in borrowing countries must be reviewed
as this has the effect of making the Bretton Woods institutions de facto
governance organizations in areas for which they are not sufficiently competent.
Instead, the Bretton Woods institutions themselves should be subjected to
internationally agreed principles, including the rules of international law
governing international economic relations, environmental safeguards, protection
of minorities and indigenous communities, etc. As international organizations,
they should be held accountable if their lending or non-lending practices
violate such internationally agreed rules and conditions in lending should only
reflect the fiduciary role of the Bretton Woods institutions in this respect and
nothing more.
The way forward
The Bretton Woods institutions have undergone significant
changes over the 60 years since their birth in the post-war period. None of
these changes have sought to change the asymmetries and inequalities which exist
within the institutions which impede their role in serving as truly multilateral
economic institutions. Instead, the constitutional amendments as well as shifts
in operational policy and practice at the two institutions have served to
reinforce such imbalances and, more worrying, to shift global economic
governance away from more democratic institutions, such as the UN, to these
organizations.
However as the discussion above has demonstrated, the
solution lays not in increasing the authority of the World Bank and the IMF by
granting these institutions more control over aspects of social and economic
development but to reduce the remit of their work to their core responsibilities
and revitalize the UN agencies which have been given mandate and have the
requisite competence to undertake the aforementioned tasks in a more democratic
manner.
References
Akyüz, Y.
(2005). “Reforming the IMF: Back to the Drawing Board”, TWN Global Economy
Series 7. Penang: Third World Network.
Akyüz, Y.
(2006). “Rectifying Capital Market Imperfections: The Continuing Rationales for
Multilateral Lending”. In Kaul, I. and Conçeiao, P. (eds). The New Public
Finance: Responding to Global Challenges. New York and Oxford: United
Nations Development Programme and Oxford University Press.
Khor, M.
(2001). “A Critique of the IMF’s Role and Policy Conditionality”. TWN Global
Economy Series. Third World Network: Penang.
Mohammed, A.A.
(2003). “Burden Sharing at the IMF”. G24 Discussion Paper Series,
December 2003.
Mohammed, A.A.
(2004). “Who Pays for the World Bank ?”. G24 Discussion Paper Series, May
2004.
South Centre
(1996). For a Strong and Democratic United Nations: A South Perspective on UN
Reform. Geneva: South Centre in association with the Non-Aligned Movement.
Wilks, A.
(2004). “The World Bank’s Knowledge Roles: Dominating Development Debates”, June
2004. London: Bretton Woods Project.
World Bank
(2005). “Review of World Bank Conditionality: Recent Trends and Practices”, 30
June 2005. Washington DC: World Bank.
School of Law, University of Warwick, UK, and the Third World Network, Asia.
Articles 1(2) of the Agreement between the United Nations and the
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1947; and the
Agreement between the United Nations and the International Monetary Fund,
1947.
For example, public expenditure management (PEM) conditions which
constituted 48% of the total share of conditionality in Bank loans in
financial year 2005 (World Bank, 2005b: Figure 11).
Article III, Section 5(b) of the IBRD Articles of Agreement; see also
Article V, Section 1(g) of the IDA Articles of Agreement.
|