2000
Globalisation and extremism: a call for a more moderate approach
Ann Pettifor
Jubilee 2000 Coalition
Re-naming is the mother of re-invention. To re-invent a company, a political party or an economic order, one must first invent a new image and name. Monsanto, the genetically modified foods company, has just changed its name to Pharmacia. So it is with the open economy. Globalisation is the new image and name of an old order: opening of the global economy to domination by the most powerful capitalist nations. The purpose is the same now as it has always been: to ensure “that capitalists from the strongest economies will be able to take advantage of opportunities for profit in other countries.”
Since
the Copenhagen Summit in 1995, world leaders of the strongest economies have
called for poverty reduction on the one hand, and sped up the process of opening
or “globalising” economies on the other. There are inherent contradictions
in this approach, which have been explored in much of development literature,
and leaders of the dominant economic nations, and their agents, the staff of the
IMF, face contradictions and inconsistencies in their approach to globalisation
itself. While promoting openness, they are reluctant to adhere to the rules of
openness and to carry out their responsibilities to those adjusting to openness.
This
“bending of the rules” and avoidance of responsibility for the project of
globalisation itself, will, we argue, further de-stabilise the international
financial system. We call for a more responsible and moderate approach from
dominant nations. Above all, we call for the enforcement of rules and discipline
in international financial relations.
The
continuum
The
merits and de-merits of an open or closed economy have been at the centre of
economic debate for a great part of our economic history.
With
the recent crises in East Asia, Russia and Latin America, these debates have
surfaced again in different form and are at the very heart of tensions within
contemporary capitalism. Pitted against the free traders at the WTO meeting in
Seattle were an extraordinary alliance of campaigners calling effectively for
protectionism—or more closed economies.
There
is no either/or in the day-to-day reality of the international economy. Instead
there is a continuum between pure closedness and pure openness on which all
nations can be located, as all nations use some combination of controls and
market freedom. The leading protagonists of open economies (the US, Japan and
the European bloc) are at the same time responsible for some of the most
effective barriers to exports from the poorest countries.[2]
In this respect, modern-day free traders are no different
from their nineteenth century “golden age” counterparts: they banned Indian cotton cloth from British markets.
The
responsibility of rich nations
For
the open economy system to work today as in the “golden age”, it is not
enough for the dominant countries to play global bullies using the IMF and NATO.
They must also—in the interests of the very openness they promote—uphold and
defend a rules-based system. The gold standard was an effective control
mechanism, precisely because it operated to strict rules, overseen and enforced
by the most powerful nation of the time, Britain.
Today
this responsibility of the most powerful nations shows signs of weakening. Clear
signs of their intention to “bend the rules” appeared in Seattle at the WTO
meeting of December 1999. The US President faced two threats to the US economic
and political system. The first: increased competition from other capitalist
nations, particularly in East Asia, which had flooded the US market with cheaper
goods and nearly doubled the US trade deficit in the previous year. The second:
the threatened loss of trade union support in the forthcoming US elections, from
workers who believe openness hurts their interests.
President
Clinton tried to react to these threats in Seattle by moving the US across the
continuum from openess to closedness. His proposals for inserting labour
standards into all trade agreements, and the use of trade sanctions to enforce
them, were perceived by developing countries as a new pretence for restricting
imports. They were not alone. The Wall St.
Journal agreed.[3]
Mr. Clinton, the Journal
argued, was evading responsibility for upholding the rules of the open or
“globalised” market. “The administration and those who support free trade
will have to respond more aggressively”, they wrote. Instead Mr. Clinton
weakened. So the Journal ran headlines denouncing Clinton as the man who had
“botched the Seattle Summit”.
This
was not the only sign of weakness in upholding free trade rules. Another is rich
country resolve to impose rules to force open capital markets, and keep
them open in times of crisis. There are signs that this resolve is
weakening. Germany’s central bank, in its December 1999 Monthly Report,
suggests that “the pace of liberalisation in capital transactions will have to
be slowed down if the underlying economic conditions of the country in question
are not yet sound enough to withstand strain.”[4]
A recent report from the IMF, which best represents the
interests and responsibilities of the richest nations, is yet another straw in
the wind. It suggests that controls limiting and disciplining capital flows may
be “useful”.[5]
The report, “Country Experiences with the Use and
Liberalisation of Capital Controls” concedes that “in India and China,
countries with long-standing and extensive controls and a cautious approach to
liberalisation, (capital) controls may have helped reduce vulnerability to the
Asian financial crisis”.
Financing
adjustment
Besides
upholding the rules for free trade and the free movement of capital, capitalist
countries have a second major responsibility if they are to keep the
international monetary order open. They must mobilise large sums of capital to
aid countries facing balance-of-payments difficulties during the transition to
openness. International credit provides a lubricant for the adjustment process,
and helps an economy move from closedness to openess. This was the role Britain
played during the “golden age” of openness.
Rich
countries promote globalisation, while evading these responsibilities to the
globalisation project itself. Aid flows have fallen steadily to USD 51.9 billion
in 1998, USD 8 billion less than in 1994. In 1980, aid levels were at an average
of 0.37% of donor GNP. With the ending of the Cold War, aid has fallen to just
0.24% of donors combined GNP, far below the UN-recommended level of 0.7% and the
lowest proportion on record.
Capital
flows to middle income developing countries increased significantly over the
1990s, with long-term flows increasing from USD 50 billion in 1990 to USD 290
billion in 1997. Short-term flows, however, proved to be hugely destabilising
with the equivalent of 10% of East Asia's GNP flowing out as panic hit investors
during the recent Asian crisis. According to the World Bank, average monthly
capital market financing for all developing countries fell from USD 25.7 billion
in July-Dec 1997 to USD 11.8 billion in July-Dec 1998.
Private
capital from the richest countries continued to bypass large numbers of
low-income developing countries, adjusting to globalisation. In 1997, South Asia
and sub-Saharan Africa together received only 6% of Foreign Direct Investment
and 12% of the aggregate net resource flows to all developing countries.
Poor
countries have no choice
Decisions
about where to place your economy on the continuum of open and closed economies
face politicians in poor countries too. However, they have less choice. The
superiority of G7 nations in nuclear weapons, control over capital, technology
and raw materials gives them great power over the poorest nations.
So
non-industrialised countries are obliged to open up their economies to western
capital and imports, while facing restrictions on their own exports into western
markets. Poor countries invariably suffer from a shortage of savings, and they
have had to cope with significant reductions in aid. They are encouraged
instead, to borrow on the international markets to finance adjustment and
development. Their economies are uncompetitive in global markets, and their
manufacturing markets often un-diversified; so the impact of openness undermines
local markets, imports deflationary pressures, worsens trade deficits, damages
the environment and hurts local communities. High levels of foreign borrowing to
finance adjustment, combined with falling export income, leads to unsustainable
levels of debt.
Which
way forward?
These
developments represent major challenges to the future of openness, or
globalisation. The outcome of these challenges is uncertain. There are signs in
the dominant nations that deflationary pressures, the adverse impact of recent
financial crises on the US and European balance of payments, economic
degradation in the poorest countries, and the debacle at the WTO will weaken
political will for the globalisation project. In the world of developing and
transition economies, the situation in some cases borders on the catastrophic.
Leaders in many countries, from Russia to the Congo, from Ecuador to Indonesia,
face social, political and economic disintegration. In the meantime, millions of
people have lost their lives or been displaced. In
1980, when Mrs Thatcher and President Reagan re-invigorated the project to open
economies, 2.5 million people were refugees. Today 21 million are displaced by
civil war, disease, famine and ecological disasters.
These
reactions to the de-stabilising impact of capital liberalisation appear to be
leading to a welcome slowing down of the pace of liberalisation. A new, more
stable and just international order, one less open than that of the last decade,
could develop. Alternatively acceleration of globalisation could lead to a
complete breakdown of the international monetary system, as happened in the
1920s and 1930s.
To
avoid complete breakdown of the international monetary system and further
economic and social degradation, we argue that the evolution of a new
international order is preferable to further opennness and financial
instability. Indeed we go further. We argue that to promote human development,
it is vital and urgent that the necessary steps are taken to move the
international economic order across the continuum and away from complete
openness.
Assert
human values over money values
In
order to promote the globalisation project, leaders and opinion-formers in the
dominant nations have had to assert the superiority of money values over human
values. This ideological framework has allowed human development to be
subordinated to the interests of capital and business development. It has
provided a pretext and cover for economic policies that have led in turn to
great loss of human life and catastrophic destruction of human potential in
developing and transition countries.
The
international Jubilee 2000 movement is a mass movement of people re-asserting
the superiority of human values over those of money, while calling for an end to
the control of moneylenders over the poorest countries.
If real commitment to poverty reduction and human development is manifest
at the forthcoming UN Summit in Geneva, then human values will have to once
again be placed above those of money. The G7 will have to stop facing both ways.
Restrain
capital flows
At
the 1997 annual meeting of the IMF and World Bank in Hong Kong, the IMF was
warned of the risks in speeding up the pace of capital liberalisation. These
warnings were arrogantly ignored. Instead, the livelihoods of millions of people
were sacrificed in the South East Asian crisis.
Joseph
Stiglitz, the former Chief Economist of the World Bank, has noted that “many
people were thrown out of jobs, and in some cases more than 50% of firms were
put into bankruptcy (during the Asian financial crisis of 1997/8)—even though
it was financial markets that were at the root of the problem”. [6]
The
IMF belatedly acknowledges that capital liberalisation played a part in
de-stabilising economies in that Asian crisis. Poor countries should be free to
learn the lessons and to control and manage flows of capital in the interests of
their own people. Chile, Malaysia, China and India have shown how this can be
done. The IMF’s grip over developing and transition economies should be
loosened so that they can follow these examples.
Introduce
discipline into lending and borrowing
As
night follows day, so reckless international lending and borrowing follows
capital liberalisation. There is great moral hazard in the absence of
regulation, as the lending to economies like Mexico, Thailand and Russia
revealed. The IMF’s determination to encourage these flows led in turn to
policies for bailing out, at taxpayers’ expense, owners of capital that had
lent carelessly. Losses and liabilities were nationalised, and future innocent
generations burdened with the debt.
This
framework encouraged market imperfections, in particular by removing risks faced
by international lenders. These creditors were not subject to the discipline of
market forces, nor to that of the law through formal bankruptcy. The
international Jubilee 2000 movement has shown unanimity in promoting a new, more
just, independent, accountable and transparent process for managing relations
between sovereign debtors and their public and private creditors.
A
fair, transparent arbitration procedure, need not be bureaucratic. It could be
modelled on the process that applied to Germany and Indonesia in 1953 and 1971
respectively. Both countries were granted massive debt cancellation by an
independent assessor. The eminent banker, Herman Josef Abs, oversaw negotiations
that shared liabilities and losses more fairly between debtors and creditors,
and gave both nations the opportunity to recover economically and enjoy a fresh
start.
Jubilee
2000 campaigns in Africa and Latin America argue that such an arbitration
process could put a brake on the corruption that takes place when loan
agreements are signed in secret. These agreements are signed in the knowledge
that neither parties to the agreement are likely to suffer losses if the debt
becomes unpayable. Local borrowing elites will have moved on. And lending elites
can either appeal to the international financial community to be bailed out; or
can wait until economic stability returns—when debts will be repaid with
compound interest. Greater transparency would restrain secretive lending by G7
government Export Credit Guarantee Departments, which use loans to promote arms
and other unproductive exports to developing countries.
An
independent arbitration process would thus have three goals: first to restore
some justice to a system in which creditors play the role of plaintiff, judge
and jury; second, to act as a brake on capital flows and introduce discipline
into sovereign lending and borrowing arrangements—and thereby to prevent
future crises; and third, to counter corruption in borrowing and lending by
introducing accountability through a free press to civil society. Such an
arbitration process would place the same disciplines on creditors as they
currently submit to under domestic bankruptcy laws, and would discourage, we
believe, the sort of reckless lending that led to the East Asian crisis. Lending
decisions would be made more carefully, with greater consideration of capacity
to repay and with a more equal share of risk between both sovereign creditors
and debtors.
Agree
deeper debt cancellation
Rich
countries have a responsibility to help poor countries cope with the
balance-of-payments crises and debts that are a necessary side effect of
adjustment to globalisation. They can do this in two ways: by offering much
deeper debt relief, and secondly by massively increasing balance of payments
support in the form of grants.
The
Highly Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative, and the USD 100 billion of
debt cancellation agreed in Cologne—while a big step forward—is nevertheless
woefully inadequate. President Clinton acknowledged as much in his address to
the IMF/World Bank annual meetings on the September 29th.
Prime Minister Tony Blair agrees and Chancellor Schroeder of Germany in a
New Year message said that “one of (Germany’s) primary tasks will be to make
further efforts to reduce the level of
debt of poorer countries”.
The
current process is entirely dominated by creditors who are deeply reluctant to
cancel debts. Furthermore it is mired in the IMF’s orthodox macro-economic
conditionalities and bureaucracy, and it and offers too little, too late for
countries in crisis, such as Guyana, Sierra Leone, Rwanda, Nigeria and Ecuador.
The relief that has already been granted means that debtor nations, including
Mozambique, Mauritania and Bolivia, will continue to spend more of their budgets
on debt repayments to rich western creditors than they spend on health,
education and clean water.
Large
debtor nations are prevented from obtaining debt relief by a method of selection
that is both arbitrary and lacking in intellectual rigour. It serves only the
interests of the dominant nations, who are keen to write off only those debts
that would anyway not be repaid. Nigeria was defined by the World Bank and IMF
as effectively bankrupt and in need of relief when the HIPC Initiative was first
drawn up. She was removed from the list by creditors, however, without
explanation. We can only conclude they were concerned about their own likely
losses.[7]
Many other countries need relief and must be freed up to
request independent arbitration and debt cancellation from their creditors.
Allow
poor countries to repay debts in their own currencies
With
the dollar as the dominant currency, the poorest countries are expected to repay
foreign debts in hard currencies, namely dollars, sterling or yen. Allowing
countries to follow the example of the United States and repay their debts in
their own currencies would return levels of debt to sustainability very quickly.
Creditors would of course hesitate to lend under these terms, but would at the
same time be more disciplined about lending. The value of poor country
currencies would rise, as creditors would have an interest in maintaining their
value. As things stand, creditors, through the IMF, have in the words of The Wall St. Journal, “a
bias toward devaluation, which is supposed to 'revive' exports even as the
inevitable, resulting inflation quickly diminishes the resident population’s
incomes and assets. Impoverishing people in this way is morally indefensible and
politically unsustainable.”[8]
Increase
the flow of aid and capital to poor countries
The
declines in aid to developing countries must be reversed. One way of raising
revenues for this purpose could be through the introduction of a Tobin Tax. Paul
Bernard Spahn has argued that a Tobin tax rate of two basis points (0.02%) on
daily turnover in foreign exchange markets of USD 1.23 trillion, could generate
USD 64 billion annually. This should be administered openly and democratically
through the UN and the revenues used and distributed for social development.
The
Tobin Tax would have an additional benefit; it would discipline and deter
speculative activity in financial markets.
Change
the focus of the IMF
Joseph
Stiglitz, until recently Chief Economist at the World Bank, has made the
powerful point that the most successful economies of the last decade—China,
India and the United States—bent the rules of openness and rebuffed IMF
macro-economic policies. “China” he has argued, “accounted for two-thirds
of the entire increase in incomes among low-income countries between 1978-1995
by largely ignoring the Washington consensus.” (Economic Journal, Nov. 1999).
China
is a powerful economy, is not crippled by debts and has nuclear weapons. Debtor
nations have no choice. They have had to adopt IMF policies. In Africa, the
consequences have been disastrous. According to the World Bank, the population
living below USD 2 a day rose by 90 million between 1990 and 1998—the period
during which the IMF dominated economic policy making on the continent.[9]
GDP per capita in sub-Saharan Africa was negative between
1989 and 1998.[10]
Over this same period, the number of people in developing and
transition economies (excluding China) living below USD 2 per day, rose,
according to the World Bank, by 1 billion.[11]
The
scale of this economic disaster is almost beyond human imagination. It has led
to social, political and civil disintegration in large swathes of the developing
world. The cost in human lives and human potential is probably incalculable and
may well exceed the lives lost during the post 1914 period. Millions of lives
have been sacrificed for an economic project that has failed to deliver economic
growth in regions such as Africa and Latin America.
In
this context, the call by the US Treasury Secretary for the IMF to give up the
role of disbursing concessional finance to developing countries and implicitly
enforcing its traditional menu of conditions, should be supported.[12]
This should only be agreed, however, if such finance continues to be made available to developing
countries – whether as direct bilateral grants, or via other development
institutions.
Localisation
not globalisation
Finally,
it is unrealistic and deeply unjust to expect the poorest countries to be able
to trade and compete fairly with the richest countries. Rwanda’s poor farmers
will never be able to compete with the subsidised, highly-capitalised and
protected grain markets of the United States, Japan or Europe.
Countries
should be free to follow the western model, namely, instituting high levels of
protection for domestic markets as they evolve and mature. Only once domestic
markets have reached a stage of genuine competitiveness, should the choice of
entering new markets be made.
Western
economies, as that great African economist Abdul Rahman Babu once argued, are
based on three pillars: agriculture, textiles and construction. These sectors
enable any nation to feed, clothe and house people. In the west they are always
protected. Under enforced opennness, developing countries are encouraged to
export raw materials, undermine subsistence agriculture and local businesses,
and turn these societies into markets for imported food and irrelevant consumer
goods. They should concentrate instead on serving the interests of local people
and their communities.
Don’t
make the poor catch up
Developing
countries are always urged to "catch up". With whom and with what?
Japan "caught up" 150 years after the UK; Sweden 50 years after
the rest of Europe. Needs are always relative. First, developing countries must
escape from debt bondage. Then they need to feed, clothe and house their people.
Only then should they borrow on international financial markets, trade and
expand. To meet basic needs, they do not need foreign loans.
This article draws on the work of Fred L Block, in his book, The
Origins of International Economic Disorder University of California
Press.
The British government stood out from the rest of their European
colleagues at Seattle by announcing they would unilaterally remove tariffs
on goods arriving from the poorest countries.
“How Clinton Botched the Seattle Summit” The
Wall St. Journal, December 6th 1999.
Deutsche Bundesbank. Monthly Report. December 1999, p. 36.
The Financial Times. January
12th 2000.
International
Herald Tribune. January 27th 2000.
See Jubilee 2000 Debt Update, Issue 3. December 1998.
Editorial. The Wall St. Journal Europe, November 11th 1999.
World Bank. Global Economic
Prospects 2000, p. 28.
Estimates of poverty by the World Bank using the $1 a day yardstick
are dubious. Full country-level documentation of impoverishment would, we
believe, reveal far greater numbers.
Larry Summers. “The IMF should focus on preventing crises”.
Independent, December 16th
1999.
|