<!-- function MM_swapImgRestore() { //v3.0 var i,x,a=document.MM_sr; for(i=0;a&&i<a.length&&(x=a[i])&&x.oSrc;i++) x.src=x.oSrc; } function MM_preloadImages() { //v3.0 var d=document; if(d.images){ if(!d.MM_p) d.MM_p=new Array(); var i,j=d.MM_p.length,a=MM_preloadImages.arguments; for(i=0; i<a.length; i++) if (a[i].indexOf("#")!=0){ d.MM_p[j]=new Image; d.MM_p[j++].src=a[i];}} } function MM_swapImage() { //v3.0 var i,j=0,x,a=MM_swapImage.arguments; document.MM_sr=new Array; for(i=0;i<(a.length-2);i+=3) if ((x=MM_findObj(a[i]))!=null){document.MM_sr[j++]=x; if(!x.oSrc) x.oSrc=x.src; x.src=a[i+2];} } function MM_jumpMenu(targ,selObj,restore){ //v3.0 eval(targ+".location='"+selObj.options[selObj.selectedIndex].value+"'"); if (restore) selObj.selectedIndex=0; } //-->
Home
 PAÍS POR PAÍS
 LOS GRANDES
 TEMAS
 AVANCES Y
 RETROCESOS
 INDICADORES
 DE DESARROLLO
  | ENGLISH | Compromisos | Informe anual Noticias | Acerca de Contáctenos  
SOCIAL WATCH INDICATORS - BOOKLET 2001

LIBERALISATION OF FINANCIAL MARKETS:
IS EVERYBODY ENJOYING THE GAME?

Marina Ponti
Davide Zanoni

Globalisation of the world economy is proceeding at a rapid pace, particularly in the arena of international finance. The presumed virtues of globalisation, however, are a long way from materializing and being fairly distributed among nations.

The opening of domestic capital markets to foreign investment is still a relevant component of the “Washington consensus”, although many experts argue that free mobility of private capital in the 1990s was responsible for the crises in emerging markets. Increased capital mobility brings high costs and limited benefits to countries with emerging markets that lack sound, modern national financial institutions and are particularly vulnerable to the volatility of financial flows.

A country can take advantage of greater capital mobility only when its domestic financial market has a sufficiently developed structure. For financially developed countries, an open capital account is a positive instrument, but in countries with weak financial structures, economic growth and social development suffer when capital accounts are opened. Moreover, countries with emerging markets and transition economies are constantly being undermined by uncontrolled and unexpected capital flight and by sudden and unsound deregulation and liberalisation policies.

The financial crises in the 1990s showed that the liberalisation process could be disastrous when it is not properly managed. Liberalisation can be extremely costly and highly dangerous in countries that do not have proper bank regulatory and supervisory structures, well-functioning legal and judicial systems, and adequate safeguards against highly risky and unethical behaviour.

Unfortunately, the above measures are far from being implemented in emerging countries. Despite their importance, such measures are unlikely to be implemented in the near term because of the complex processes involved.

There are temporary measures, however, that can be taken to protect vulnerable national economies from financial instability before strong financial structures are in place. Amongst others, these include limits on loan-to-value ratios and consumer credit, maximum repayment periods and minimum down-payment percentages. Additional measures that reduce vulnerability of national financial systems include restrictions on foreign-denominated debt and prudential controls to limit capital inflows.

Chile’s experience with capital controls in the 1990s is a concrete example of such a temporary measure. Chile introduced restrictions on capital inflows in June 1991. Initially, all portfolio inflows were subject to a 20% reserve deposit with no interest. For maturities of less than one year, the deposits applied for the duration of the inflow, while for longer maturities the reserve requirement was for one year. In July 1992, the rate of the reserve requirement was raised to 30%, and its holding period was set at one year, independently of the length of the flow. The results achieved by the authorities with this policy have been so far:

a decrease in the volume of short-term inflows and an increase of longer maturities. (As shown in Table 1, the reduction in shorter-term flows was fully compensated by equivalent increases in longer-term capital inflows. Thus, aggregate capital inflows to Chile were not decreased by capital controls!);

a decrease of the country’s vulnerability to international financial instability;

the ability of the central bank to implement an independent monetary policy (despite the presence of pegged exchange rates) and to maintain a high differential between domestic and international interest rates.

This example shows that temporary measures such as restrictions on capital flows, like those implemented in Chile, are useful instruments that safeguard financial stability, prevent financial crises and encourage long-term capital inflows. Thus, without a stable and sound international financial system, capital controls can be considered as valid, safe and valuable policy options to promote development. Furthermore, the policy dilemma of the “impossibility of the holy trinity” –that is, achieving free capital mobility, a pegged exchange rate and an independent monetary policy simultaneously– is false. There is no valid argument or evidence to support the need for full liberalisation of capital markets and flows at all cost. On the contrary, ad hoc measures to control capital flows, specifically designed and implemented for each individual country, should be pursued by national governments and strongly encouraged by international institutions.

TABLE 1: Capital Inflows (gross) to chile: Millions of USD

YEAR

SHORT-TERM
FLOWS

PTAGE.
OF TOTAL

LONG-TERM
FLOWS

PTAGE.
OF TOTAL

TOTAL

DEPOSITS*

1998

916,564

96.3

34,838

3.7

951,402

/

1989

1,452,595

95.0

77,122

5.0

1,529,717

/

1990 1,683,149 90.3 181,419 9.7 1,864,568

/

1991 521,198 72.7 196,115 27.3 717,313

587

1992 225,197 28.9 554,072 71.1 779,269

11,424

1993 159,462 23.6 515,147 76.4 674,609

41,280

1994 161,575 16.5 819,699 83.5 981,274

87,039

1995 69,675 6.2 1,051,829 93.8 1,121,504 38,752
1996 66,254 3.2 2,042,456 96,8 2,109,710 172,320
1997 81,131 2.8 2,805,882 97.2 2,887,013 331,572
* Deposits in the Banco de Chile due to reserve requirements
Source: Central Bank of Chile

 

In analysing the evolution of the financial market, it is essential to focus on the composition of financial flows and their ability to support development. In the past two decades, the combination of liberalisation, speculation and technology innovation has given rise to a system of huge dimensions that functions more on rumour than on economic fundamentals. The main players in this system, inter alia commercial and investment banks, exchange USD1,862 billion daily in currency transactions and Over The Counter Transactions (OTC). Moreover, the currency market has grown. Table 2 shows that foreign exchange transactions increased from USD18.3 billion/day in 1977 to USD1,500 billion in 1998. With derivative transactions added, this figure is USD1,597 billion. Furthermore, from 1977 to 1998, the ratio between annual currency value in foreign currency and foreign export increased from 3.51 to 55.97, while the ratio of central bank reserves to daily currency activities in foreign currency decreased from 14.5 to a mere 1.

Table 3 shows that 40.1% of contracts are two-day spot transactions, 41.7% are three to seven days, and only 1.1% are for more than one year. It should be noted that contracts on currencies are purely speculative. This market is beyond any public control and totally disconnected from productive activities.

International trade of goods and services took place at a slower pace. The total amount of the goods traded in 1998 was USD6,700 billion, registering a 14% growth rate from 1995. Financial activities involve 76 times more financial resources than global trade in goods and services: for each dollar spent on trade, USD75 are invested in financial assets.

TABLE 2: Daily average turnover in currency exchange markets in 1998, by length of contract (in USD millions)

MATURITIES

2 DAYS

3-7 DAYS

1 YEAR

>1 YEAR

TOTAL

%

1. Spot

577,737       577,737

40.1

2. Outright

65,892

58,680

5,099

129,671

9.0

3. Forward            
4. Forex swaps 530,683 192,592 10,847 734,122

50.9

Total 577,737 596,575 251,272 15,946 1,441,530 100.0
% 40.1 41.4 17.4 1.1 100.00

Source: B.I.S (1998)

 

 

TABLE 3: Official Reserves, foreign exchange
trade and exports, 1977-98 

YEAR Official Reserves
(USD billions)
Reserves+Gold
(USD billions)
Daily Global Turnover
(USD billions) *
Reserves/
Daily Turnover
  (1) (2) (3) (1)/(3) (2)/(3)
1998 1,636.1 1,972.0 1,500.0 1.0 1.3
1995 1,347.3 1,450.0 1,190.0 1.1 1.2
1992 910.8 1,022.5 820.0 1.1 1.2
1989 722.3 826.8 590.0 1.2 1.4
1986 456.0 23.0 270.0 1.7 2.0
1983 339.7 494.6 119.0 2.8 4.2
1980 386.6 468.9 82.5 4.7 5.7
1977 265.8 296.6 18.3 14.5 16.2
*Excluded derivative contracts

Source: B.I.S. (1998)

 

The most alarming consequence of these trends is that central banks have lost the capability of reacting to speculative attacks. Global central bank reserves are equivalent to the amount traded in one day of currency transactions on financial markets. Data from March 1999 show that this situation is worsening.

These considerations yield the following controversial issues:

the volume of short-term capital flows, in particular massive inflows and outflows of speculative capital (spot transactions), leads to substantial exchange rate instability;

the excessive liquidity of financial markets means that national institutions such as central banks are unable to protect national currencies from speculative attacks. Traditionally, a central bank buys and sells its national currency on international markets to keep the currency’s value relatively stable. The bank buys currency when a glut caused by an investor sell-off threatens to reduce the currency’s value. In the past, central banks had reserves sufficient to offset any sell-off or attack. Currently, speculators have larger pools of cash than all the world’s central banks together. This means that many central banks are unable to protect their currencies, and when a country cannot defend the value of its currency, it loses control of its monetary policy.

Elimination of the above phenomena requires a consistent reform of the global financial architecture and thus should be seen as a long-term goal of the international community. Meanwhile, a more immediate measure could be implemented: a currency transaction tax (CTT). A uniform international tax payable on all spot transactions involving the conversion of one currency into another, in both domestic security markets and foreign exchange markets, would discourage speculation by making currency trading more costly. The volume of short-term capital flows would decrease, leading to greater exchange rate stability.

Achieving this stability through taxation would require high rates, however, and this would seriously obstruct the workings of international financial markets. A small charge on international financial transactions would not create distortions, but it would also not inhibit speculative behaviour in foreign exchange markets. One possible compromise, suggested by Paul Bernd Spahn, Professor at the University of Frankfurt, would be a two-tier structure: a minimal rate transaction tax and an exchange surcharge that, as an anti speculation devise, would be triggered only during periods of exchange rate turbulence. The minimal rate transaction tax would function on a continuing basis and raise substantial, stable revenues without impairing the normal liquidity function of world financial markets. It would also serve as a monitoring and controlling device for the exchange surcharge, which would be administered jointly with the transaction tax. The exchange surcharge, which would be dormant as long as foreign exchange markets operated normally, would not be used to raise revenues, but would function as an automatic circuit-braker whenever speculative attacks against currencies occurred. A minimal nominal charge of, e.g., two basis points on foreign exchange transactions, would raise the cost of capital insignificantly and would probably have no effect on the volume of transactions involving currency conversions. The exchange surcharge would avoid the negative effects of other monetary policy measures that sacrifice valuable international reserves or offer excessively generous interest rates to combat speculative attacks. It would also eliminate expectations of recurrent bailouts by central banks and reduce unethical behaviour and the impacts of financial crises.

To summarise, the implementation of a CTT could:

reduce short-term speculative currency and capital flows;

enhance national policy autonomy;

restore taxation capacity of individual countries eroded by the globalisation of markets;

distribute tax pressures more equitably among different sectors of the economy;

trace movements of capital to fight tax evasion and money laundering.

In addition, the CTT could collect resources for development purposes. The revenues generated by a CTT should not, however, replace the fulfilment of fundamental commitments, such as the internationally agreed level of official development assistance (ODA), adequate debt reduction and cancellation initiatives, and a more equitable trade agreement.

The overall objective should be the design of new rules for an international financial system based on a more equitable redistribution of benefits and costs. Redistribution should be at the heart of the political agenda in this new Millennium, so that we can reach social and economic development for all.

Mani Tese
rel.esterne@manitese.it

University of Castellanza-LIUC

 

 

 

Imprimir subir

 

  | ENGLISH | Compromisos | Informe Anual| Noticias | Acerca de Contáctenos   
Buscar
en Control Ciudadano en Internet con Choike

Instituto del Tercer Mundo - Control Ciudadano

Control Ciudadano es una red internacional de organizaciones ciudadanas que informan sobre la erradicación de la pobreza y la igualdad de género.

Jackson 1136, Montevideo 11200, Uruguay
Tel: + 598-2-419-61-92. Fax: + 598-2-411-92-22
e-mail: socwatch@socialwatch.org